This is the old United Nations University website. Visit the new site at http://unu.edu
Energy sector use and transformation
Electricity generation
Electricity generation in Brazil is dominated by hydropower
(94 per cent). As already noted, we assume that hydropower
generates zero net CO2 emissions. We expect that this
share will fall by 2000. In the official SNE scenarios, the share
falls from 94 to 85-88 per cent (ELETROBRAS 1990). Here we assume
a moderate shift to thermal generation such that hydropower falls
to 90 per cent of total generation by the year 2000. By then, 20
per cent of newly available generating capacity coming on-line
would be thermal (of which 10 per cent would be coal-fired; 40
per cent would be natural-gas-fired; 30 per cent would be
fuel-oil- and refinery residues-fired; and 20 per cent would be
biomass-fired). We estimate that generating 1 GWhe would result
in 37.2 TC emissions in Brazil in 2000, an increase from today's
9 TC/GWhe. This coefficient would be very low by international
standards. The analysis also assumes that 16 per cent of total
generated electricity is lost in transmission and distribution
losses incurred in delivering power to the residential,
commercial and public illumination sectors.
The shift to greater thermal generation is a response to a series of problems faced by the power sector. These include: a profound financial crisis (hydropower is capital intensive); the large market uncertainty confronting supply planning (larger hydropower has long lead times); and the need to attract more private sector investment in generation, which tends to favour thermal power plants. A more hydropower-intensive scenario is conceivable but we have not reviewed this possibility as it would require extensive, system-level analysis beyond the scope of this chapter. It is noteworthy, however, that Brazil's thermal electrical sector would not be very carbon-intensive.
Other energy transformation
This end use includes all energy inputs to extract and
process fuel oil rigs, refineries, sugar plantations, etc. Half
of the sectoral carbon emissions are due to the conversion of
fuelwood to charcoal. As is generally the case with biomass fuels
used in industry, the production of charcoal is inefficient. This
inefficiency can be greatly reduced; this must be done in any
case to ensure that fuelwood from sustainably managed forests for
charcoal manufacture is economically viable. Reducing conversion
waste in the charcoal fuel cycle will deliver the biggest
abatement of carbon emission in the subsector. Although less
dramatic, incremental improvements in efficiency are also
available in most industries. These small but pervasive gains
would accumulate into significant reductions of fossil fuel usage
and carbon emissions.
Electricity final demand
Electricity generation will remain a relatively small source of CO2 emissions for many years in Brazil. Yet it is still desirable to reduce these emissions by demand side management. Many of these opportunities to increase efficiency have a large 'negative cost.' exploiting these opportunities will also relieve the financial pressures felt by the electrical sector in Brazil.
Residential sector
The residential sector consumes about 22 per cent of total
electricity and contributes 30-37 per cent of the electricity
evening peak. We have considered a range of technical options
that could be implemented in this sector up to 2000. For each of
the following final uses, we estimated the carbon abatement that
can be obtained by improving electricity end-use efficiency:
lighting, water heating, refrigeration and air conditioning. In
Table 10.7, we show the technical and economic specifications for
the new technologies and those being replaced; the amount of
carbon abated per year per unit of equipment; the levellized
annual cost of the new technology; and, in the last column, the
net costs when the annual value of the electricity saved is
deducted from the levelized costs.) A negative figure means that
the new technology brings economic savings, even before
considering carbon credits.
Table 10.7 Residential sector technologies to limit CO2 emissions implementable by 2000
Old technology (1) | New technology (2) | Avoided C (kg/y/unit) (3) | Levelized annual cost ($/kg C) (4) | Annual cost of saved elec. ($/kg C )(5) | Net annual cost ($/kg C) (d) = (4-5) | Total C avoided (MTC/y) | Total net cost (million $/y) | |
Incandescent bulb (standard) | Efficient incandescent | 0.260 | 0.192 | 1.989 | -1.797 | 0.0385 | -69.26 | |
Lifetime (h) | 1000 | 1000 | ||||||
Power (W) | 60 | 54 | ||||||
Usage (h/y/lamp) | 1000 | 1000 | ||||||
Cost (US$/lamp) | 0.50 | 0.55 | ||||||
Incandescent bulb (standard) | Fluarescent (standard) | 1.560 | 0.485 | 1.989 | -1.504 | 0.1386 | -208.40 | |
Lifetime (h) | 1000 | 8000 | ||||||
Power (W) | 60 | 24 | ||||||
Usage (h/y/lamp) | 1000 | 1000 | ||||||
Cost (US$/lamp) | 0.50 | 7.00 | ||||||
Incandescent bulb (standard) | Compact fluorescent | 1.910 | 1.338 | 1.989 | -0.651 | 0.1129 | -224.50 | |
Lifetime (h) | 1000 | 8000 | ||||||
Power (W) | 60 | 16 | ||||||
Usage (h/y/lamp) | 1000 | 1000 | ||||||
Cost (US$/lamp) | 0.50 | 17.00 | ||||||
Electric shower | Solar shower | 17.350 | 4.146 | 1.989 | 2 157 | 0.2563 | 553.00 | |
Lifetime (y) | 15 | 15 | ||||||
Consumption (kWh/y) | 500 | 100 | ||||||
Cost (US$/unit) | 10.00 | 500.00 | ||||||
Refrigerator (standard) | Efficient refrigerator | 5.210 | 2.255 | 1.989 | 0.266 | 0.0857 | 22.80 | |
Lifetime (y) | 15 | 15 | ||||||
Consumption (kWh/y) | 600 | 480 | ||||||
Cost (US$/unit) | 200 | 280.00 | ||||||
Air conditioner (standard) | Efficient air conditioner | 7.460 | 1.297 | 1.989 | -0.692 | 0.0170 | -11.80 | |
Lifetime (y) | 12 | 12 | ||||||
Consumption (kWh/y) | 860 | 688 | ||||||
Cost (US$/unit) | 490.00 | 550.00 |
Lighting
Based on the present stock of residential lamps (220 million
incandescent lamps and eight million fluorescents), we estimate
the stock in 2000. We assume that 50 per cent of old, inefficient
incandescents will be replaced by efficient incandescents; 30 per
cent by fluorescents; and 20 per cent by compact fluorescents.
Such a programme would reduce carbon emissions by 0.29/MTC in
2000, providing a total net annual levelized benefit of US$502
million.
Water heating
In 1987,75 per cent of Brazil's 26.3 million electrified
households had electric showers. Assuming that the number of
showers increases by 2.1 per cent per year up to 2000 and
further, that solar water heaters achieve a 50 per cent
penetration level in that year, we estimate that another 0.256
MTC can be conserved at an annual net cost of US$553 million.
Refrigeration
Refrigeration accounts for about 33 per cent of total residential
electricity use and is very wasteful (Jannuzzi and Schipper 1991;
Geller 1991). We projected the stock of refrigerators in the year
2000 based on today's stock of 27 million. Assuming that 50 per
cent of the stock in 2000 is efficient, we estimated that 0.086
MTC can be abated at a total net cost in that year of US$22.8
million.
Table 10.8 Commercial and public sector technologies to limit CO2 emission* implementable by 2000
Old technology(1) | New technology(2) | Avoided C (kg/y/unit)(3) | Levelized annual cost ($/kg C) (4) | Annual cost of saved elec. ($/kg C) (5) | Net annual cost($/kgC) (6) = (4-5) | Total C avoided (MTC/y) | Total net cost (million $/y) | |
Incandescent bulb (standard) | Efficient incandescent | 0.830 | 0.229 | 2.690 | -2.461 | 0.0053 | -12.95 | |
Lifetime (h) | 1000 | 1000 | ||||||
Power (W) | 100 | 48 | ||||||
Usage (h/y/lamp) | 1920 | 1920 | ||||||
Cost (US$/lamp) | 0.80 | 0.90 | ||||||
Incandescent bulb (standard) | Fluorescent (standard) | 4.330 | 1.309 | 2.690 | -1.381 | 0.0618 | -111.16 | |
Lifetime (h) | 1000 | 8000 | ||||||
Power (W) | 100 | 48 | ||||||
Usage (h/y/lamp) | 1920 | 1920 | ||||||
Cost (US$/lamp) | 0.50 | 22.50c | ||||||
Incandescent bulb (standard) | Compact fluorescent | 2.290 | 1.345 | 2.690 | -1.345 | 0.0485 | -96.26 | |
Lifetime (h) | 1000 | 8000 | ||||||
Power (W) | 60 | 16 | ||||||
Usage (h/y/lamp) | 1200 | 1200 | ||||||
Cost (US$/lamp) | 0.50 | 17.00 | ||||||
Fluorescent (standard) | Efficient fluorescent | 1.000 | 0.990 | 2.690 | -1.700 | 0.0645 | -109.68 | |
Lifetime (h) | 8000 | 8000 | ||||||
Power (W) | 48 | 36 | ||||||
Usage (h/y/lamp) | 1920 | 1920 | ||||||
Cost (US$/lamp) | 7.00 | 10.00 | ||||||
Incandescent bulg (standard) | Mercury/sodium | 15.050 | 1.928 | 1.548 | 0.380 | 0.015 | 5.74 | |
Lifetime (h) | 1000 | 12000 | ||||||
Power (W) | 175 | 80 | ||||||
Usage (h/y/lamp) | 3650 | 3650 | ||||||
Cost (US$/lamp) | 1.00 | 80.00b |
a Includes lamp (8000h), ballast
(12000h) and light fixture (20000h).
b Average cost of mercury and sodium package with 80% mercury
lamps.
Air conditioning
We assumed that 2.85 million air conditioners will be in use in
residences in the year 2000. Of this total, 80 per cent will be
installed after 1990. We further assumed that all will be energy
saving units. On this basis, 0.017 MTC can be conserved in 2000
at a total net benefit of US$11.8 million per year.
Commercial, service sector and public lighting
Total energy consumption of the commercial and services
sectors has increased threefold during the past fifteen years,
and electricity accounts for more than 90 per cent of the
increase. We considered only opportunities to increase the
efficiency of lighting. In Table 10.8. we present the technical
and economic data for the new and old technologies, and
quantities and costs of carbon abatement. We assumed the current
tariff for commercial electricity of US$0.10/kWhe. (In the
future, we would prefer to use an estimate of the economic cost
of electricity). We also assumed that 26 million incandescent and
48 million fluorescent lamps were used in these two sectors in
1990 (Jannuzzi et al 1991). We postulated a 2 per cent annual
growth rate for incandescent sales and 3 per cent for
fluorescents (taken as 40W lamps). We estimate that all the
incandescent lamps could be replaced in the year 2000 as follows:
20 per cent by krypton-filled bulbs; 45 per cent by standard
fluorescents; and 35 per cent by compact fluorescents. This
substitution would conserve 0.116 MTC of emissions and increase
total net benefits that year by US$220 million. Replacing all
fluorescents of 40W with more efficient 32W units with electronic
ballasts would conserve another 0.064 MTC, and increase total net
benefits by US$110 million.
In Table 10.8, we also present results for improvements in public illumination. If 800,000 incandescent lamps are replaced by mercury lamps and 200,000 by sodium lamps, then 0.015 MTC could be conserved at an annual cost of US$5.7 million.
Industrial sector
To calculate industrial electricity demand in 2000, we
assumed an average industrial economic growth of 3.5 per cent per
year (as suggested by the low growth 'tendencies' scenario) and
the same energy intensity (total energy/ GNP) as in 1988. We
analysed electricity consumption for each industrial subsector
and factored in technological improvements believed to be
currently economic. We included the following measures:
housekeeping; efficient lighting; and more efficient electric
motors, variable speed electric motors, electric ovens, and
electrolytic processes. We priced industrial electricity at an
average US$0.0581kWhe. In Table 10.9, we list technical and
economic data for these improvements.
Table 10.9 Industrial sector technologies to limit CO, emissions, implementable by 2000
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4)=(2)-(3) | |
Avoided carbon (MTC/y) |
Levelized annual cost (US$/TC) |
Annual cost of saved electricity (US$/TC) |
Net annual cost (US$/TC) |
|
Housekeeping measures | 0.32 | 409 | 1560 | -1151 |
Lighting | 0.02 | 988 | 1 560 | -572 |
High efficiency motor | 0.115 | 383 | 1560 | -11 77 |
Variable speed drivers | 0.197 | 357 | 1560 | -1203 |
Electric ovens and boilers | 0.152 | 197 | 1560 | -1363 |
Electrolytic processes | 0.075 | 389 | 672 | -283 |
Housekeeping measures
From many evaluations performed by electric utilities (CEMIG
1989; CESP 1990) it is clear that electricity demand can be
reduced by 10 per cent with better end-use management. These
measures should include:
a better choice of electric motor size, especially by avoiding oversized motors which are common (Latone e' al 1990);
appropriate design of the factory's internal electric distribution grid;
installation of small size transformers in parallel with the main one, to be used during idle factory periods;
correction of the load factor;
avoidance of short term peak demand (through the use of demand controllers); and
better mechanical coupling between electric motors and the equipment driven by them.
These actions would conserve 0.32 MTC for a total annual net benefit of US$368 million.
Lighting
The industrial sector contains about 14 million fluorescent 40
watt lamps. We assumed that this stock grows by 3.5 per cent per
year and that all new lights will be the 32 watt efficient type
(with new ballast). These steps would conserve 0.020 MTC/year
yielding a total annual net benefit of US$11.3 million.
High efficiency electric motors
These devices are available in Brazil and offer an improved
average efficiency of 7 per cent. We assumed that 60 per cent of
motors will be replaced by high efficiency models up to the year
2000. This step would save 3.1 TWhe in that year (Geller 1991),
saving Brazil US$135 million and avoiding 0.115 MTC emissions.
Variable speed electric motors
Variable speed motors can be run partly loaded without decreasing
energy efficiency. More important, in applications such as
refrigeration and air circulation, such motors can operate partly
loaded with less energy consumption than do fixed frequency
motors that provide only on/off cycles. About 30 per cent of the
total motor market (measured in kWhe/year) is used to drive
variable loads. If half of this load is met by variable speed
motors, Brazil would reap a total annual net benefit of US$237
millions and conserve 0.197 MTC.
Electric ovens and boilers
At least 10 per cent of the electricity used in electric ovens
and electric boilers can be avoided by recycling the exhaust heat
or by installing more efficient equipment (Geller 1991). We
expect that the retrofit rate will be low. Nonetheless, one third
of the potential saving could be achieved by the year 2000. We
estimate that the total annual net savings that year would be
US$207 million, thereby conserving 0.152 MTC.
Electrolytic processes
Studies on electricity intensive industries (CNE 1989) have shown
that improvements in electrolytic processes can reduce
electricity consumption by 7 per cent in metallurgical industries
and by 10 per cent in chemical industries. Brazil could avoid
generating 2 TWhe by this means in 2000, saving a total annual
net benefit of US$21.2 million and reducing carbon emissions by
0.075 MTC.
Final electricity demand summary
Modern technologies can improve end-use electricity
efficiency, although their cumulative impact on carbon emissions
is small in a country like Brazil where most of the electricity
is provided by hydroelectric power plants. We estimate that the
potential to conserve carbon in the residential, commercial,
service, public illumination and industrial sectors in 2000 is
about 1.7 MTC - or only about 3.2 per cent of the total fossil
fuel carbon emissions of 1990. This result follows from the
predominance of hydroelectricity supply in Brazil. Nonetheless,
these technologies should be promoted in any case because most
bring net economic benefits. The few which involve net costs
today should become cheaper as the technology is accepted more
widely and economies of scale are achieved. The only high cost
technology where this trend may not hold is solar heating to
replace electric showers.
Final fuel demand
The final consumption of fuels is the predominant source of CO2 emissions in Brazil (see Table 10.3). We focus on the transport sector in this section because it is the largest source of fossil CO2 emissions.
Transport
Transport is central to the achievement of carbon emission
abatement. In Brazil, this sector is responsible for 44 per cent
of fossil carbon dioxide emissions. Most (82 per cent) of these
emissions come from road transport (SNE 1991b). Transport-related
carbon emissions result from three broad factors: the carbon
emission coefficient of the fuel used; the efficiency with which
different energy forms are used in different modes and markets;
and the demand for transport services in different markets and
different modes that serve these markets.
In this section, we review the measures which influence these three determining factors in the transport sector. Fuel substitution can modify the first factor, the carbon emission coefficient. Vehicle efficiency affects the second. 'Structural charges' influence both the demand for different modes of transport; and the performance of the vehicles operating within them, that is, the second and the third factors listed above. These first two classes of measures are dominated by energy sector objectives and priorities. The economics of the third, the category of 'structural charges,' is determined by non-energy societal benefits. Consequently, economic analysis of the third factor is more complex than for the first two.
Fuel substitution
The emergence of CO2 emissions as an issue will
have a profound effect on the development of substitutes for
petroleum derivatives in the long run. The only large scale
commercial substitutes in the world which reduce rather than
increase emissions are ethanol from sugarcane (the production of
which is concentrated in Brazil) and compressed natural gas.
Alcohol
Brazil's well-known alcohol programme (PROALCOOL) now fuels
nearly five million Brazilian cars with pure (hydrated) ethanol.
The rest use a gasoline-alcohol mixture. PROALCOOL is now in a
difficult situation due to the collapse of oil prices in 1986.
Some have suggested that alcohol output should be reduced
gradually (World Bank 1990). We have not calculated the societal
cost of maintaining current output, nor the cost of increasing
the output level. Such an estimate should include the impact on
sugar prices of reducing alcohol output (Borrel 1991) and on
employment - especially in the Northeast where the sugarcane
industry is in crisis. However, the net cost of merely
maintaining the output of alcohol should be lower than for
expanding it (see Table 10.10).
The 'alternative' SNE scenario projected moderate growth of 2.1 million of tonnes of oil equivalent (MTOE) or 37 per cent by 2000, thereby increasing the market share of ethanol from 17 per cent to 19 per cent of total transport fuel. We adopted this estimate in our own scenario. This substitution would conserve about 1.5 MTC (see Table 10.10), even allowing for fossil fuel inputs for alcohol production. The net cost of this expansion is heavily influenced by assumptions as to gasoline prices. At a gasoline price of US$25 per barrel, we estimated the net cost of expansion to be US$2301TC. Changes in alcohol production technology may also substantially reduce costs by improving the utilization of the residues of sugarcane processing in the cogeneration of electricity. In Brazil, conventional steam turbine technology does not offer much hope of reducing alcohol production costs. But the new gasification/gas turbine (BIG/GT) technology could reduce costs significantly (Ogden et al 1990). Table 10.10 illustrates this possibility. Such major reductions are likely to be commercially proven only by the end of the decade.
Table 10. 10 Transport sector opportunities to limit CO, emissions by 2000, preliminary
Avoided CO2 (MTC)a | Net cost/TC (US$)a | |
FUEL SUBSTITUTION | ||
Alcohol: maintain existing output | 4.2 | not availableb |
Alcohol: expand output | ||
Current technology at $25/b gasoline | 1.5e | 230c |
Current technology at $35/b gasoline | 1.5e | 115c |
New technology at $25/b gasoline | very small | 75d |
New technology at $35/b gasoline | very small | -35d |
Natural gas | 0.2f | near zero (+,-) |
VEHICLE EFFICIENCY | ||
Improvement in automobiles | 1.9-2.5k | -135i |
Diesel engine | 0.9h | -30/-40 |
STRUCTURAL CHANGE | ||
Highway system recovery | 2.4g | 800g |
Improved urban transportation | 0.4-0.8l | near zero (+,-) |
a Includes rough estimates of fossil fuel inputs for alcohol
production (15% of alcohol output) and of refinery efficiency for
gasoline (95%). Elsewhere in column a 95% refinery efficiency is
assumed.
b Estimated to be lower than increasing alcohol output. Baseline
scenario assumes maintenance of existing output.
c Assumes a litre of hydrated alcohol is equivalent to 0.7 litres
of gasoline (small efficiency credit).
Cost of good exiting distillery is $0.20 per litre. Allows for
refinery efficiency of 95% in gasoline production and fossil fuel
inputs equivalent to 15% of alcohol production.
d Assumes alcohol production cost of $0.14 litre, only available
by end of the decode.
e Based on 'alternative' scenario relative to 1990 (see text).
f Based on 'alternative' relative to 'tendencies' scenario.
g Assumes baseline of 14 MTOE diesel consumption and 3.7 MTOE
gasoline in 2000 compatible
with 'tendencies' scenario assuming same proportion of total
diesel and gasoline transport use
as today. Assumes an average 15% improvement for all vehicles.
While up to 40% improvement
is possible from worst to best conditions, not all of the roods
needing improvement, about 50%
of the roads are in the 'worst' category.
h Assumes 25% of market of 21.4 MTOE in 'tendencies' scenario
shifted to this engine type.
i Assumes conservatively average vehicle use at 45,000 km per
year with 3-year engine lifetime,
engine 25% mare expensive and average efficiency improved by 15%.
j Assumes existing gasoline price ($0.26 per litre). Average cost
of measures is $0.17 per litre,
adjusting cast estimates of Ledbetter and Ross (1990), for 12%
discount rate.
k Ledbetter and Ross (1990) estimate US average fleet fuel
economy could increase 25% by
2000. Assume here that in 'tendencies' baseline average Brazilian
fuel economy increases to existing US level (estimated at 9.2
km/litre).
l See text. This is the least defined case. It helps to
illustrate the impact of a relatively small effort to improve
urban transportation.
Natural gas
Natural gas is promoted as a substitute for diesel, primarily in public transport. The main goal is to reduce atmospheric pollution (NOx, SOx, particulates) in metropolitan areas. Several cities aim to replace all diesel in vehicle fleets by around 2000. The 'alternative' scenario estimates that 0.9 MTOE of natural gas may be used in this fashion which would conserve O2 MTC. Some of this gas may displace gasoline instead of diesel, since this is more lucrative at current relative prices. The cost of the measure (excluding environmental benefits) is near zero. That is, the natural gas option roughly breaks even with diesel at today's prices.
Road transport vehicle efficiency
Significant improvements in vehicular fuel economy are
possible. The rate of improvement will be determined primarily by
technological innovation in the automotive industry in the
industrialized countries and secondarily, by the pace that these
changes penetrate the Brazilian market.
Light vehicle efficiency
The current Brazilian automobile averages about 7.5 km/l
(gasoline equivalent). The SNE 'tendencies' scenario projected an
increase of 30 per cent in light vehicle (basically automobile)
fuel consumption to 17 MTOE, incorporating modest improvements in
fuel economy. We extrapolated from US data on trends in
automobile fuel efficiency (Ledbetter and Ross 1990), and
considered only measures that cost less when operated at the
consumer retail price of gasoline today. On this basis, we
estimated that the average fuel use of the automobile fleet could
be decreased by 20-25 per cent relative to the 'tendencies'
scenario, saving 3.4-4.3 MTOE of fuel per year.) The associated
carbon abatement depends on whether these savings cut gasoline
rather than alcohol usage. If we assume that two-thirds of the
fuel saving is gasoline, then carbon emissions would fall by
1.9-2.5 MTC. Based on US costs, the average cost of these
measures would be negative (see Table 10.10) - even if we ignore
the likely benefits of reducing the emissions of other local
pollutants. Our projected large fuel saving contrasts strikingly
with that of the SNE official 'alternative' scenario, which
projected that only 0.4 MTOE could be saved by increasing
automotive fuel efficiency.
Heavy vehicle efficiency
We estimated heavy vehicular fuel use from figures available for
diesel consumed by Brazilian road vehicles. On this basis, this
end use in 1990 was 15.5 MTOE. The SNE 'tendencies' scenario
projected that it would increase to 21.5 MTOE. More efficient
diesel engines offer substantial fuel savings at a zero or
slightly negative net cost (Cummins 1991). We assumed that 15 per
cent of the fuel can be saved in this sector. As the initial cost
of the engine is about 25 per cent greater than less efficient
motors, the net cost would be US$30-401TC conserved. If the more
efficient motors achieved a 25 per cent additional market share
than in the SNE 'tendencies' scenario, then another 0.9 MTC would
be conserved. Other measures can improve heavy vehicle fuel
economy, including improved maintenance and motor regulation and
more appropriate sizing of vehicles to their tasks.
Structural changes
In this section, we outline structural changes that foster
energy efficiency. These are: the re-paving and rehabilitation of
the existing highway system; and the reform of urban transport to
improve public transport and the overall productivity of urban
transport infrastructure. Both approaches entail large public
sector investments in which non-energy costs and benefits usually
determine policy decisions. Broad rather than narrow economic
analysis must be used to estimate the economic feasibility of
these changes.
Highway systems recovery
Brazil has an extensive, but badly deteriorated, intercity
highway system. Roughly half of its 130,000 km system requires
intense reconstruction. The economic cost of this decayed
infrastructure is high in terms of trip time and reliability,
vehicle maintenance and lifetime, and hazard. The poor system
also reduces energy efficiency. For inter-urban trucks and buses
the loss may be as high as 40 per cent on poor quality paved
roads relative to well-maintained roads (GEIPOT 1989). Assuming
an average fuel economy gain of 15 per cent and a baseline
interurban vehicle fuel consumption consistent with the
'tendencies' scenario, CO2 emissions in 2000 could be
reduced by about 2.4 MTC. The investments required are large and
the lifetime of the assets is as short as five years (Lee 1991).
The cost (if fully charged to carbon abatement) could exceed
US$8001TC conserved (including only fuel savings). Much - perhaps
most - of this reconstruction is economically justified without
reference to carbon emissions. In that case, the energy savings
and carbon abatement can be treated as a by-product obtained at
zero marginal cost.
Improved urban transportation
Approximately one third of transport fuel is consumed in the
capital cities and larger metropolitan areas. Changes in the
structure and operation of the urban transport systems can
influence the evolution of fuel demand, though the evaluation of
this potential is still in its infancy. Measures are diverse and
include land use control, disciplining the automobile's use of
road space, coordinating traffic flow and strengthening
collective transport (Poole et al 992).
The city of Curitiba has already addressed the problem of urban transport in a comprehensive manner. The city has coordinated urban land use, roadspace and collective transport policy for more than fifteen years, and has improved bus systems and traffic controls. Fuel consumption per car in Curitiba is about 30 per cent less than the average for other cities of its size in Brazil (Lerner 1989). This differential may indicate the potential impact of such measures if adopted widely in Brazil.
An aggressive programme to address urban transport imperatives might result in CO2 emissions savings of 5-10 per cent relative to the SNE 'tendencies' scenario for 2000. This potential could be realized in spite of the inertia of a decentralized system involving thousands, even millions of actors. If lower cost solutions are emphasized in the next decade, then this energy and carbon savings could be achieved at zero net cost. Such measures would include creating and integrating public transport systems, and controls on traffic flow and parking.
By far the largest source of anthropogenic carbon dioxide emission in Brazil is deforestation, principally in Amazonia. The carbon stock of the seasonal and rainforest vegetation in Amazonia is estimated to range from 140 to 200 TC/ha; that of pasture is 10 TC/ha; and of cropland, 5 TC/ha. The forest carbon stock may be adjusted as new information becomes available on subsurface biomass of the vegetation. Changing land use also reduces soil carbon content. In pasture soil, for example, the carbon content may be about 10 per cent of the approximately 100 TC/hectare of forest soil, or about 90 TC/ha. less than in forests. (Houghton et al 1991).
Thus, assuming a deforestation rate in Amazonia of 1.8 million hectares per year, gross CO2 emissions would be 250-360 MTC (though not all appears immediately in the atmosphere). To this figure should be added emissions from deforestation in other regions of Brazil. Unfortunately, we have no estimates for this source. Although substantially smaller, these are not insignificant.
Biological processes also continually accumulate carbon from the atmosphere, as is the case with regrowth of natural vegetation on deforested areas, abandoned land, or forest plantations. The rate of natural regrowth can vary by a factor of twenty in humid tropical areas depending on the local land-use situation (Nepstad et al 1990). The scale of this countervailing sequestration is poorly understood.
Despite these uncertainties, it is clear that Brazil's annual emissions from deforestation (250-360 MTC) dwarf those of fossil fuel use (60 MTC) as well as from biomass use for energy (about 11 MTC). This fact is consistent with the observation that fuelwood use is not a major factor in overall deforestation, though it may be significant in some regions (for example, charcoal from cerrado and mangroves). The primary direct causes of deforestation are clearing for pasture and cropland, with logging often opening up the occupation process.
Focusing on Amazonia, any substantial decrease in the rate of deforestation is likely to be associated with decreased economic growth. Macroeconomic modelling suggests that for every 1 per cent reduction in deforestation regional GDP would have to fall by roughly 1.7 per cent (Reds 1991). While pessimistic, the model suggests a first approximation of the cost of CO2 abatement by halting deforestation, roughly US$4/TC according to the model's author. This low cost (equivalent to a tax of $0.50/barrel of oil) is probably an upper limit, since the model assumes historical relationships. A strategy to change these relationships should be both cheaper and allow a less drastic trade-off between economic growth and deforestation. Such a strategy must go beyond police enforcement or reducing/eliminating legal and financial incentives to deforestation, though these are important (for example, Binswanger 1991). New or modified economic activities must be developed or strengthened both in forested and deforested areas (Sawyer 1990) based on land-use zoning. Settlement and economic activity, for example, should be stabilized, consolidated, and (in many areas) intensified in the largely deforested areas along the frontier and the 'pre-frontier'. While complex, restructuring Amazonia's economy is likely to be a large, 'no regress' source of CO2 abatement.
The relationship between land-use trends and energy policy has been little explored in Brazil. The most important such interaction is fuelwood for industry and charcoal. This nexus is the most important direct energy-related source of deforestation. A key issue is whether a decisive move to put these uses on a sustainable basis is justified or whether they should be phased out.
Another important land-use issue in relation to energy arises from hydroelectricity development in Amazonia. The relative priority, rate of development, and ultimate potential may all be influenced by a strategy to minimize deforestation. The infrastructure and migrations occasioned by hydro are the key concern. Some projects may provoke deforestation. Others help to decrease it as, for example, on the Tocantins river (Moreira et al 1990). This indirect effect on carbon emissions is likely to be larger than differences in direct electricity CO2 emissions resulting from alternative scenarios of hydropower/thermal generations (as discussed above).
Two subsidiary issues also connect land-use and energy policy issues. The unavailability of electrical power to isolated communities (most especially in Amazonia) constrains economic development. Poverty, in turn, fosters more carbon-emitting and intensive resource exploitation (Poole et al 1990). Relatedly, fuels such as diesel sold for use in Amazonia are subsidized (Reds 1991). The common denominator of CO2 emissions reinforces the need to consider energy, land use and regional development together.
The analysis of CO2 evolution and abatement measures is still incipient in Brazil both in regard to energy and to land-use change. The creation of credible, systematic and internationally comparable 'abasement cost' curves for Brazil is still not possible. As a consequence there is as yet little basis on which to agree on specific CO2 limitation targets. The problem is exacerbated by the wide range of uncertainty surrounding the prospects for economic growth. The work briefly described here is part of an effort to better understand the potential and economics of CO; abatement. In Figure 10.1, we summarize the tentative results of this study for the costs and abatement potential of measures to reduce fossil energy emissions. We identified about 13.7 MTC of technologically feasible and economically justified carbon abatement, relative to the SNE 'tendencies' scenario in the year 2000. This reduction potential amounts to about 16 per cent of the SNE reference projection for carbon emissions in that year. We did not allow for the more pervasive energy and carbon reducing effects of technological innovation in all end-using sectors; nor did we include the impact of shifts in the sectoral composition of the economy on our estimate of energy and carbon conservation. Moreover, as our bottom-up calculation is extended to other sectors, we expect to increase substantially the size of the carbon reduction potential above 13.7 MTC.
Figure 10.1 Cumulative annual carbon emissions avoided by 2000 for technology improvements in Brazil
Although the quantitative analysis is incomplete and preliminary, it permits some observations which are relevant for policy. It appears that substantial savings in CO2 emissions can be achieved at 'negative cost' or very low cost (say, less than US$10/TC), both in energy and land-use change. These savings should be substantially cheaper than those of many measures being considered by the industrialized countries. However, the fact that these are 'no regress' sayings does not mean that they are easy to achieve. This fact is relevant for a possible policy of international resource transfers, which should be very attentive to 'no regrets' opportunities in developing countries.
In Brazil's energy sector, the major 'no regress' sayings involve increasing energy efficiency in all consuming sectors. As explained earlier, conditions and policies favouring greater energy efficiency are also likely to favour, and are associated with, higher medium term economic growth (low inflation, correct price signals, investment in modernizing processes and products, competition, etc). Energy efficiency itself should directly contribute to improved overall productivity and thus to economic growth.
With regard to land-use change, we argue that the trade-off between Amazonia's economic growth and reducing deforestation is not so acute as some suggest. However, a strategy is needed urgently to change the economic dynamics of Amazonia's frontier regions. The case of Amazonia also highlights the need for cost-benefit analysis to explicitly consider who pays the costs and who receives the benefits of policy changes aimed at conserving carbon.
The medium term potential for relatively low cost CO2 abatement is probably much larger for land-use change than in the energy sector. This judgement does not mean that energy efficiency should be ignored, however. Many measures to reduce energy-related emissions are as cost effective, or even more so, than those to reduce emissions from land-use change. Moreover, energy is fast becoming relatively more important. Finally, as we have observed, energy policy can influence future land-use, especially in the Amazon region.
Using the technologies discussed in this chapter, the total amount of carbon abatement is approximately 13.5 million TC. In Figure 10.1, we plotted a total amount of 9.3 million TC, since we excluded the 4.2 million TC due to the use of alcohol at the existing output (as shown in Table 10.10) because we did not know the net cost associated with this technology. The opportunities identified in this chapter are not the complete picture. Other technologies exist, and with their full inclusion on the demand side of the Brazilian energy matrix, probably more CO2 abatement than is forecasted in the official alternative scenario can be achieved.
Ayres, R U (1991) 'No regrets options for greenhouse gas abatement,' in A Comprehensive Approach to Climate Change, ed. T Hanisch, Center for International Climate and Energy Research, Oslo
Binswanger, H (1991) 'Brazilian Policies that Encourage Deforestation in the Amazon', World Development, 19(7)
Borrel, P (1991) 'How a Change in Brazil Sugar Policies Would Affect the World Sugar Market,' PRE, Working Paper, World Bank, Washington DC
CEMIG (1989) Companhia Energética de Minas Gerais, 'Estudo de Economia de Energia', Belo Horizonte-MG, Brazil
CESP (1990) Companhia Energética de São Paulo, Personal communication, São Paulo, Brazil
CNE (1989) Comissão Nacional de Energia, 'Estudo Sobre Energo Intensivos, Assessoria Tecnica', April, 1989, Brasilia, Brazil
Cummins Newsletter (1991) published by Cummins Engine Co. Inc., Columbus, USA
ELETROBRAS (1990) Programa Decenal de Geração 1991/2000, Sistemas Interligados SE/CO/S, N/NE. Planning of Grupo Coordenador do Planejamento dos Sistemas Eletricos, Rio de janeiro, Brazil
GEIPOT (1989) Empresa Brasileira de Planejamento de Transportes. Manual para Cálculo de Custos Operacionais de Veículos Rodoviários, Ministério dos Transportes, Brasilia, Brazil
Geller, H (1991) Efficient Electricity Uses: a Development Strategy for Brazil, American Council for an Energy Efficient Economy, Washington, DC, USA
Houghton, R A, Skole, D L and Letkowitz, D S (1991) 'Changes in the landscape of Latin America between 1850 and 1985: II Net release of CO2 to the atmosphere,' Forest Ecology and Management, 38, pp 173-199
Jannuzzi, G M, Gadgil, A, Geller, H. Sastry, A (1991) 'Energy efficient lighting in Brazil and India', Proceedings of the 1st European Conference on Energy-Efficient Lighting, Stockholm, 28-30 May
Jannuzzi, G M and Schipper, L (1991) 'The structure of electricity demand in the Brazilian household sector', Energy Policy, 19(11)
Latone, COF. Nobre, E C and Burgoa, J A ( 1990) 'Diagnóstico do Potencial de Conservação de Energia na Industria' Proceeding of the 5th Congresso Brasileiro de Energia 'desafio dos anos 90', November 5-9,1990. Rio de Janeiro, Brazil
Ledbetter, M, and Ross, M (1990) 'Supply Curves of Conserved Energy for Automobiles'. Lawrence Berkeley Laboratory, Berkeley, USA
Lee, S H (1991) Planning Manager, Secretaria de Transportes e Obras, Santa Catarina, Brazil, Oral Communication
Lerner, J (1989) 'Curitiba Mass Transit Systems', Workshop on New Energy Technologies, Transportation and Development, International Institute for Energy Conservation, Washington DC, September
Moreira, J R and Poole, A D (June 1991) 'Energia e Melo Ambiente', Secretaria de Ciencia e Tecnologia, Federal Government, Brasilia, Brazil
Moreira, J R and Poole, A D (1992) 'Hydroelectricity and its Constraints' draft for publication, ed. Thomas Johansson, 'Fuels and Electricity from Renewable Sources of Energy', Island Press.
Moreira, l R. Poole, A D and Serrasqueiro, M A (1990) 'Alternatives Energéticas da Amazonia'. Part IV of Projeto/Análise da Implantação de Grandes Projetos Energéticos - O Caso do Setor Elétrico do Brazil. Institute of Electrotechnology and Energy. University of Sao Paulo
Nepstad, D, Uhl, C and Serro, E A (1990) 'Surmounting Barriers to Forest Regeneration in Abandoned Highly Degraded Pastures, A Case Study from Paragominas, Para, Brazil', in Alternatives to Deforestation, ed. Anthony Anderson, Columbia University Press, New York
Ogden, J M, Williams, R H and Fulmer, M E (1990) 'Cogeneration Applications of Biomass Gasifier/Gas Turbined Technologies in the Cane Sugar and Alcohol Industries', Center for Energy and Environmental Studies, Princeton University, Princeton
Poole, A D, Ortega, O and Moreira, J R (1990) 'Energia pare o Desenvolvimento da Amaznia ', Instituto de Eletrotécnica e Energia for UNDP/SUDAM, Macrocenários Amazonia 2010, Belém, Brazil
Poole, A D, Pacheco, R S and Melo, M A C (1992) Collective Transport Policy in Developing Countries: A Case Study of Brazil, International Development Research Institute, Ottawa
Reis, E (1991) 'A Amazonia e o efeito Estufa, Perspectivas da Economia Brasileira 1992, IPEA - Instituto de Pesquisas e Economia Aplicada, Brasilia, Brazil
Sawyer. D (1990) 'The Future of Deforestation in Amazonia: A Socioeconomic and
Political Analysis', in Alternatives to Deforestation, ed. Anderson, Columbia University Press, New York
SNE (1991a) 'Reexame da Matriz Energetica Nacional', Ministerio da Infraestrutura, Federal Government, Brasilia, Brazil
SNE (1991b) 'Balanco Energetico Nacional', Secretaria Nacional de Energia, Ministerio da Infraestrutura, Federal Government, Brasilia, Brazil
USDOE (1990) The Potential of Renewable Energy, Interlaboratory White Paper, Office of Policy, Planning and Analysis, Washington DC
World Bank (1990) Brazil Energy Strategies and Issues Study Pricing and Investment Policy, Washington DC