This is the old United Nations University website. Visit the new site at http://unu.edu


            

Asia and Africa into the Global Economy:
Background and Introduction

Julius Court
United Nations University

and

Toru Yanagihara
Hosei University

I. Introduction

The entry point for the paper is the premise that the globalisation of the world economy is one of most important trends that affect the current environment for economic development. When evaluating the different regional performance within the context of globalisation, there has been a tendency to contrast the sustained and rapid growth in per capita income in Southeast Asian economies over the last three decades with the stagnation in the levels of per capita income in sub-Saharan Africa. There can be no doubt that one of the remarkable features of the performance of Southeast Asia over the last three decades has been their ability to expand and upgrade their linkages with the world economy. Similarly, there is certainly concern over the increased marginalisation of much of Africa. In seeking to integrate into the global economy. Southeast Asian experiences could provide valuable lessons that policy-makers in sub-Saharan Africa could adapt to their own contexts. But, recent events in Southeast Asia have stimulated concern over certain aspects of their development strategies. It is also therefore a timely moment to take another look at the experiences of Southeast Asia in light of these issues.

The purpose of this paper is to draw out some of the key themes that contrast the external performance of Southeast Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa. Drawing on the debate around the key lessons from the East Asian experience, we will first develop a framework within which different strategies for integration can be discussed. We distinguish between the economic policies and the institutional foundations for successful external performance. Furthermore, we will distinguish between measures that create general conditions for development of an overall economy, including successful external performance, and those that are specifically targeted to the external sector. Countries in Southeast Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa seem to have pursued a mix of these two strategies with varying degrees of success. The question of transferability of any lessons is taken up at the end of the paper.

The paper is organised as follows. Section II provides the background and rationale for comparing Southeast Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa. Section III describes a general framework for classifying measures to promote integration into the global economy. Section IV discusses general and specific economic policy approaches for successful external performance. Section V discusses general and specific institutional foundations for external performance. Section VI undertakes a brief comparison of Southeast Asia and Africa in the four key issues concentrated on in the project. Section VII looks at the issue relating to the potential transferability of lessons from Southeast Asia to Africa. Section VIII concludes and highlights key issues for clarification.

II. Background and Rationale for Comparing Southeast Asia and sub-Saharan Africa

Given the rapid rates of development in East Asia over the last three decades there has been a considerable amount of effort devoted to distilling the lessons from East Asia and their transferability to other developing countries. Much of the existing literature on economic performance in East Asia and Africa has concentrated on studies that focus on a particular region. Two much noted reports of this kind by the World Bank are The East Asian Miracle Study (World Bank, 1993) and the Adjustment in Africa Study (World Bank, 1994).

Within the group of High-Performing Asian Economies, as classified by The East Asian Miracle (World Bank, 1993), we can distinguish four subgroups or tiers according to the level of industrial development as well as the sophistication of economic system. The first tier consists of Japan with its century long history of industrial development and highly autonomous institutional structure. The second tier consists of Taiwan and Korea with their post-WWII trajectories of limited but continual industrial diversification and deepening and records of high and sustained economic growth. A third, slightly separate tier, consists of the city-states of Hong Kong and Singapore. These have both developed into centres of regional trade although with different governance structures. The final tier comprises the economies of Southeast Asia - Malaysia, Thailand, and Indonesia. Initially, natural resources and primary exports played a pivotal role in their development but their production structures and external performance have undergone a substantial quantitative and qualitative improvement over the last thirty years.

The experiences of the fourth tier group can probably be most meaningfully compared to Sub-Saharan African economies. In the 1960s, the average levels of GDP in Southeast Asia (Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand) and sub-Saharan Africa were similar. Also, economic structures and the social contexts of countries in Southeast Asia in the 1960s were not apparently so different from those of some African countries. Southeast Asia could be characterised as being relatively rich in natural resources but weaker in human resources. This is similar to the situation in many countries in sub-Saharan Africa both in the 1960’s and today. Southeast Asia also had problems of ethnic conflict and periods of political instability. At the time (circa early 1960s), many expected rapid growth in Africa and stagnation in Asia (see discussion in Harriss, 1997).

There are also a number of recent studies directly comparing Southeast Asia and sub-Saharan Africa. This project hopes to add value to existing studies in four main ways.

First, there is no comprehensive comparison of the two regions regarding integration to the global economy, which would include the various aspects of the globalisation process, such as trade, industrialisation, FDI and capital flows. The rationale for this broad approach is based on the argument that such issues are part of the same process in the modern globalising world and should be studied in an integrated way (Helleiner, 1998).

Second, the dominant focus in the literature is on economic policy. Although some of the studies mention institutional factors, there remain very few systematic analyses of these aspects despite the fact that the importance of institutional factors is increasingly recognised. In this regard, the work of the African Economic Research Consortium (AERC) in undertaking a comparative institutional analysis of East Asia and Africa is certainly a very valuable contribution (Nissanke and Aryeetey, 1997).

Third, the project is using experts from each region with the aim of getting a deeper understanding as well as to promote an unfiltered exchange of knowledge between the two regions.

Fourth, the project has been aligned to be policy-oriented in parallel with the TICAD process. One of the main themes of the process is Asia-Africa collaboration. Having said that, it is more by luck than design that a significant part of the proposed main message of TICAD II concerns integrating Africa into the global economy. The message reads "accelerated and sustainable growth for poverty alleviation and strengthening Africa’s participation in the global economy" (emphasis added). Therefore, in addition to discussing the papers we hope to use the workshop to focus on some of the main policy messages that could be incorporated into the "agenda for action", the output of TICAD II.

The rest of this section will give a brief outline of the differences in growth and external performance between the two regions. Graph 1 outlines the changes in GDP per capita in Southeast Asia and Africa since 1970. It powerfully illustrates the divergence in the level of GDP since the early 1980s. However, there is also a range of performances within Southeast Asia (see Graph 2) and Sub Saharan Africa (see Appendix 1). Malaysia in particular had a head start on other countries in Southeast Asia whereas Indonesia started from a position below the African average.

The literature identifies the greater outward orientation in Southeast Asia as one of the main causes of the difference in growth performance with Sub Saharan Africa. Taking export performance as an example, the difference between Southeast Asia and Africa in is highlighted in Graphs 3-6. Graph 3 shows that the value of Southeast Asian countries exports have grown rapidly in comparison to those of selected countries from Africa. Graphs 4 and 5 show that export growth rates were higher in Southeast Asia for every 5-year period since 1970 and the divergence in performance in a few sample countries. It is important to outline the extent of the relative marginalisation of sub-Saharan Africa. In the mid-1950s Sub-Saharan Africa accounted for 3.1 percent of global exports. By 1995 this share had fallen to 1.4 percent. Sub-Saharan Africa is the only region of the world where export volumes have grown more slowly than total output. Africa has also failed to maintain market share in the commodities in which it had a comparative advantage. In addition, many countries in Africa attract virtually no inward investment - the region as a whole accounts for less than 1% of world investment flows (Collier, 1995).

Source: Calculated from World Development Indicators, 1997.

Source: Calculated from World Development Indicators, 1997.

Source: Calculated from World Development Indicators, 1997.

Source: Calculated from World Development Indicators, 1997.

Source: Calculated from World Development Indicators, 1997.

Source: Calculated from World Development Indicators, 1997.

Countries in Southeast Asia have also upgraded their linkages with the world economy; in other words, there has been a qualitative improvement. This has included a diversification in primary exports and an upgrading into the export of primary-processed and manufactured products. In addition, particularly since 1987, Southeast Asia also attracted large amounts of direct and portfolio investment. These issues are discussed in detail in section VI below.

The analysis of GDP performance indicates clearly that it was not until the early 1980s that the disparity in GDP performance between the two regions started to become so pronounced. This has tended to lead researchers to look primarily at the period from the 1980s, when searching for lessons from Southeast Asia (Harrold et al., 1996). The brief analysis of export performance indicates the need to take a longer-term view. Countries in Southeast Asia had growing levels of exports from much earlier and, although the results were not immediately evident in growth performance, they seemed to lead to impressive performance in the longer term.

But it is important to make two qualifications. First, the ongoing crisis in Southeast Asia highlights the need to rethink the Asian lessons and to focus on some of the severe challenges for economic management (and not just the growth opportunities) presented by the globalisation of the world economy.

Second, it is important to distinguish between the differential situations and performance of countries within Africa. Appendix 1 gives an initial indication of the wide range in rates of growth between countries in African. There are some African successes. Botswana for example has had growth rates that are the fastest in the world grown at over the last 30 years. More recently, countries such as Uganda and Ethiopia and are making significant progress (Appendix 2). In terms of external performance, Mauritius has been very successful in linking with the global economy. In contrast, countries such as Sudan and Sierra Leone continue to suffer the effects of civil war with the resulting implications of poor growth. Also some key states, Kenya, Nigeria, Democratic Republic of Congo and Zimbabwe, for example, remain in fragile condition.

Overall, the recent economic performance in Africa has shown signs of improvement. In 1997, economic growth for Sub-Saharan Africa was estimated at around 4.6% compared to 4.5% in 1996 and 3.3% in 1995. Last year 21 countries (out of a total of 48) had a GDP growth rate of 5% or more and at least 38 countries had positive GDP per capita growth rates (World Bank Africa Brief, 1998). Particularly interesting in regard to this meeting is that exports grew by 7.5% in 1995 and 7.9% in 1996. Some are asking whether Africa is turning the corner? While some attribute this to policy reforms, others highlight the good weather and improvements in world prices. While this performance is welcome, it must be remembered that this growth should be seen in the context of a population growth rate that remains near 3%. There has not been an improvement in savings or investment and nearly 40% of the population of 600 million people live on less than $1 per day. The World Bank estimates that there will need to be sustained (and broad-based) economic growth of around 7-8% if poverty is to be reduced significantly".

One of the key ways to improve the growth rate to these levels will be for African countries to engage the forces of globalisation more successfully. A key aim for this project is to try to identify: (i) What does Africa need to do to engage globalisation more effectively? And (ii) What can Africa learn from the experiences Southeast Asia in this regard?

III. A Conceptual Framework for Measures to Promote Integration

This section provides a framework for characterising and contrasting the different measures and approaches that countries have pursued in their effort to integrate with the global economy. Let us first provide a schematic overview of the issue areas covered in this paper (Table 1). The measures government adopts with the aim of promoting integration (or development in general) are classified into one of the four boxes in this two-by-two diagram. This is meant to be a simple classification scheme - there will be ambiguities both across the general/specific divide and across policy/institution divide.

"General" denotes those measures intended to impact the overall economy; "specific" indicates that the intended impact of measures is limited in scope. The use of the term specific in this paper broadly corresponds to that of sector in either functional (e.g. external and internal sectors) or substantive (e.g. industrial sectors) classifications of economic activities. To rephrase, "specific" measures only influence economic activities in a certain sector, while "general" measures have impact throughout the economy.

Table 1: General and specific measures

   General measures Specific measures

Economic

Policies

Institutional

Foundations

     

As a matter of definition, specific does not necessarily imply selective: specific measures may be applied in a non-selective, non-discriminatory manner. Similarly, again as a matter of definition, specific does not necessarily imply proactive or promotional: specific measures might be concerned with just setting the rules of the game without providing any particular inducement mechanisms. In reality, however, specific measures tend more often to be adopted in a selective and proactive mode.

"Policies" refer to courses of actions or decisions in functional terms. They are expressed as principles, orientations or concrete targets. "Institutions" signify the rules and arrangements governing the behaviour of economic, bureaucratic and political actors.

To give an initial indication of how our classification scheme would work, please refer to the Table 2 below. It shows various goals and measures adopted by government in the pursuit of better external sector performance. Section IV and V provide more detail from Southeast Asia and Africa on each of these quadrants.

Table 2: to be added

Prior to that, it is important to look more closely at two issues: (i) Inter-relations and Priorities between General and Specific Measures, and (ii) Inter-relations between Institutions and Policies. In this regard, the approaches in two recent World Bank publications – the East Asian Miracle (hereafter EAM) and the 1997 World Development Report (hereafter WDR97) on the State in a Changing World are used as reference points for our discussion.

Interrelations and Priorities between General and Specific Approaches to Integration

The central question consists of the place and role of specific measures in relation to general measures. There could be a range of positions on this. First, at one extreme, the neoclassical position is essentially "general measure fundamentalist" - it argues that all that is needed is general measures. The general approach encompasses economic policies and institutional preconditions which have an impact throughout the economy. It is conducive to better external performance by creating a stable political and economic framework, liberalising and levelling the playing field. These conditions will create profitable investment opportunities for private firms to realise, reflecting the economy’s comparative advantage.

Second, at the other extreme, the neostructuralist perspective is "specific measure fundamentalist" and would argue that specific measures are also vital for the long-term dynamism and sustainability of development process. Proponents would claim that competitive advantages need to be continually created and upgraded through government measures specifically focused on targeted sectors. For example Lall and Stewart (199?) assert that "whatever the level of country's industrial development, there is a need for selectivity to reach the next stage" (p. 202).

Third, there will be in-between positions that emphasise complementarity and synergy between general and specific approaches. Such an approach would advocate general measures but would also advocate specific measures towards tilting of the playing field in favour of the external sector activities. In this regard, the line between "market friendly" and selective interventions is almost impossible to draw. This can be illustrated using the two World Bank reports mentioned above.

The East Asian Miracle Study (EAM) characterisation of a functional approach to growth classifies policies into "Fundamentals" and "Selective Interventions" (see Table 3 for a summary). Regarding general economic policies, it emphasises the overriding importance of prudent macroeconomic management and resulting macroeconomic stability as an indispensable precondition for economic growth in general and external sector development in particular. It also acknowledges the importance of selective interventions, characterising export push as "a winning mix of fundamentals and interventions" (World Bank, 1993: 22). But the report plays down the importance of specific economic policies noting that "price distortions arising from selective interventions were … less extreme than in many developing economies" (p. 7).

Table 3: to be added

Similarly, the 1997 World Development Report (WDR97) discusses the advisability of specific and/or selective approaches under the heading of "Can state activism enhance market development?" (pp.72-75). WDR97 concurs with the proponents of activist roles of the government in that it identifies the information and co-ordination problems inherent in private-sector decision-making as critical hindrance to marked-based economic development. It states: "Countries whose markets are underdeveloped may need some catalyst, public or private, to set this cumulative process of market thickening and network development in motion" (p.74). It cites the following examples as illustration of catalytic role of the government:

    • special support for exports
    • strengthening of local infrastructure (physical, human, and institutional)
    • public-private partnerships

But in this connection, WDR97 lists three critical background conditions that are needed for activist governments to be successful in the market-enhancing role: first, mutual trust between government agencies and private companies; second, discipline of competitive market pressures; and third, conformity with evolving comparative advantage as guidance of selectivity.

Lall (1997) provides a very useful analysis of the case for and against selective interventions. This is summarised below:

For: There is a valid case for interventions if more realistic assumptions are accepted regarding the nature by which comparative advantages are developed. There is increasing acknowledgement of the extent of market failures in developing countries. Market failures (and the intervention to help deal with them) can take, among others, three forms:

  • within firms (provide information and a cushion for learning through protection)
  • in inter-firm relations (co-ordination of investments partly by protection, geographical clustering and promoting linkages)
  • factor markets (by direct interventions to remedy the failure)

Note: Protection can only work if part of package that offsets the deleterous impacts of protection and addresses the other market failures.

Against: But it is vital to bear in mind the risks of government failure. These include

  • Lack of clarity of objectives – governments often have unclear or conflicting objectives in their economic or trade policies. At least "leaving it to the market has the advantage of being clear. It would seem to be a basic condition that any government that undertakes industrial policy have a clear, well-publicised and credible set of objectives where efficiency and export growth have top priority.
  • Lack of information – governments wishing to undertake selective measures need information on market parameters and therefore this is posed as one of the main constraints to selectivity. But it must also be noted that private agents also face problems in this respect. The real challenge for developing countries lies in finding out the basic parameters of new technologies (efficient scales, sources of know-how and equipment, skill needs, international market size and access) and in assessing the availability of the local capabilities and suppliers. Jumps should not be too large or non-commercial.
  • Agency problems – There is a need to ensure that the ‘implicit’ contract is enforced. In particular, the Tigers used export performance as the allocation and monitoring device.
  • Skills – Selective strategies can be very demanding of technical and administrative skills, which are often in short supply in developing countries. But small and simple strategies can be chosen that need not be any more demanding than market friendly policies.
  • Resource constraints – most intervention requires financial resources as well as human ones.
  • Co-ordination with the private sector – The importance of close co-ordination between the government and the private sector is often noted.
  • Inflexibility – Many interventions turn out to be costly not because of initial design but because of the difficulty in changing course. The use of export performance is perhaps the best way to monitor export policies.
  • Sectional interest – The risk of the hijacking of policies by sectional interests is greater for selective policies than for functional policies.
  • Corruption – At lower levels, changes in monitoring, employment and incentives may help reduce corruption. If there is no genuine commitment to economic development, there is no way of mounting selective, or indeed any useful development, policies. The greater the risk of corruption the less selectivity should be exercised.

The situation is clearly not one of free market versus wholesale intervention – there is agreement on both sides on the importance of comparative advantage, market failures and institutional weaknesses of the government, albeit with differing degrees of emphasis. Deciding whether or not to undertake specific interventions and the type and level of any intervention will depend on an assessment on the specific needs that are of greatest importance to each country and whether the pre-requisites are in place. There is likely to be a need to strike a balance between the promotion of efficiency (through international competition) and the strengthening of capabilities (through building up human capabilities with investment in education and upgrading economic capabilities with protective and promotional measures).

Interrelations between Policies and Institutions

Policies and institutions interact in a number of ways. First of all, policies are outcomes of the institutional system of policy formulation. Second, policies are implemented within the institutional system of policy execution. Thirdly, and conversely, policy decisions and their outcomes set conditions on the operation of institutions and thus impact on their functioning. It is useful to discuss the impact of the quality of institutions on the type of policies that should be attempted.

The recent World Development Report 1997 (WDR97) presents a systematic examination of the relationships between policy and institutional factors in discussing the role and capability of the state. The central message is summarised as a two-part strategy: first match the state’s role and function to its capability; and second strengthen capability. The first part of the strategy entails, for many developing countries, focusing state’s capability on fundamental tasks. WDR97 offers a new, broader list of socio-economic fundamentals comprising: establishing a foundation of law; maintaining a non-distortionary policy environment, including macroeconomic stability; investing in basic social services and infrastructure; protecting the vulnerable; and protecting the environment (p.4).

WDR97 applies a similar logic to the question of "how" as well as that of "what" to do. In discussing alternative approaches to regulatory and industrial policies it introduces the concept of "institutional intensity". The message is that countries with weak institutional capabilities should not adopt "institution intensive" approaches to policy. This reflects the advice for developing countries in EAM that export push places less demand on institutional capacities of the government than other components of the selective interventions menu, which have been deployed more systematically in North East Asia.

This position of WDR97 boils down to what might be called "general approach prioritisation". In this approach central focus is placed on getting "overall policy and institutional environments" right. Specifically, policy distortions must be limited and legal, administrative and judicial rules must exist, and be enforced, to provide general conditions for market mechanisms to operate effectively. When institutional capabilities are scarce, they must be focused on meeting these general institutional foundations.

Although there is some validity to this argument, it is not clear that specific policies are any more complex than trying to manage the macro economy. Specific trade, industrial and technological policies should not necessarily be ruled out due to the lack of capacity. The key issue revolves around what are the most important policy needs for each country or what the bottlenecks are. If general policies are in place and, for example, "export push" was seen as valuable to the economy then the state should allocate capacity and/or undertake rapid training of key personnel. But, if the general policy and institutional foundations are not in place a country should not be distracted into considering such specific measures. It is important to clearly weigh up the benefit of any policy / institutional arrangement against the direct and opportunity cost of undertaking it.

IV. Economic Policies and External Performance in Asia and Africa

We intend to concentrate on: (a) general economic policies and external performance in Southeast Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa and (b) specific economic policies for integration in Southeast Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa.

4.1 General Economic Policies

There is a degree of consensus, however, between both proponents of general and specific approaches to integration on the advisability of general economic policies for promoting development and encouraging integration with the global economy in particular. Such policies would include:

  • investment in human and physical capital (education and transport & communication infrastructure);
  • stable macroeconomic environment (including for example - maintaining low inflation; maintaining stable and positive real interest rates, keeping budget deficits and external debt manageable);
  • Greater outward orientation (including maintaining a competitive and stable exchange rate; low levels of tariffs and quotas; and openness to foreign technology and investment).

There is a substantial body of work revolving around the two World Bank reports on each region - World Bank (1993) on East Asia and World Bank (1994) on sub-Saharan Africa - that indicates the importance of these issues. See Table 4 below for a comparison of these issues for Southeast Asia and Africa. There is widespread acceptance that sound general policies highlighted above were a central part of Southeast Asia’s outward oriented development strategy.

Table 4: Macroeconomic Indicators for SE Asia and SS Africa

Indicator

Period

 

Southeast Asia

Sub-Saharan Africa

Growth GDP/capita %

1961-93

 

4.3

0.3

Avg. Budget Balance

1979-90

 

-2 to 2

-3 to –8

Gross Domestic Savings

(% of GDP)

1967-73

1974-80

18.9

28.1

15.7

20.7

1981-90

31.9

12.6

Gross Domestic Investment

(% of GDP)

1967-73

1974-80

20.1

21.0

17.3

17.9

1981-90

22.1

19.1

Source: Harrold et al, 1996 and world Development Indicators 97

There are a number of explanations for Africa’s marginalisation in the literature. Past debate has tended to concentrate on a particularly hostile external environment facing Africa or alternatively on the inappropriate domestic policy regimes maintained in most African countries. While there is some evidence that Africa did face external shocks the weight of evidence certainly suggests that African states made poor policy choices (see World Bank, 1994; Easterly and Levine, 1995; Harrold et al., 1996; Sachs and Warner, 1996: Ng and Yeats, 1997).

Based on the view that inappropriate policy was the problem there was a firm belief that removing such impediments to markets would boost growth and improve external performance substantially. This led to the stabilisation and structural adjustment policies. There is evidence that growth and export performances have been somewhat better in countries that have undertaken and sustained a reasonable measure of macroeconomic reform. Taking trade as an example, World Bank (Wang and Winters, 1997) and AERC studies (results reported in Collier, 1997) have shown that trade liberalisation has been associated with improved export performance.

It is argued that there has not yet been enough reform (World Bank, 1994; Collier, 1995). In particular, there is still a great need to reduce anti-export bias. Trade regimes in Africa are still significantly more restrictive and complex than in other parts of the world (Calamitsis, 1998). He argues that eliminating exemptions and reducing tariffs would not only enhance efficiency and competetiveness but also reduce the opportunities for corruption. But this will be politically difficult to achieve. Trade taxes still amount to some 40% of fiscal revenue in a representative African country (World Bank, 1998). Therefore tariff reduction will need to be part of broader fiscal reform. In addition, liberalisation of imports is often politically sensitive.

However, although there is little debate that such reform was needed, there seems to be emerging agreement that "getting the prices right" in Africa, though necessary, is not sufficient to lead to significant and sustainable progress in linking with the global economy. Taking trade as an example, Africa’s performance remains disappointing in terms of (i) the weak growth of total merchandise exports (ii) the continued concentration in primary exports and (iii) the concentration of the market in Western Europe (Blackhurst and Lyakurwa, 1997).

Their remain a number of constraints that policy reform alone will not rectify. In this regard, it is important to highlight issues such as a high-risk environment characterised by political and policy uncertainty, weak agencies of restraint and insufficient scale (Collier, 1995), the existence of market failures and the very low base of human capital and technological development (Oyejide, 1997). This has led to increasing emphasis placed on the importance of institutional issues (see Section V).

4.2) Specific Economic Policies for Integration

Specific economic policies related to external sector would include:

  • export preference policies – e.g. duty rebates/exemption schemes, and trade financing and marketing mechanisms;
  • FDI preference policies – e.g. fiscal and financial incentives, and exemptions from regulations;
  • free trade zones and export processing zones
  • specific industrial policy – e.g. infant industry protection/promotion
  • industrial skill and technology development programs
  • agricultural policy – e.g. support for research and extension, and rural infrastructure

Debate continues, empirically as well as analytically, regarding the importance of specific policies for the impressive external performance of East Asia. A number of commentators argue that specific policies were not particularly important in Southeast Asia (e.g. Hill, 1996). In interpreting and drawing policy lessons from East Asia, EAM does acknowledge the effectiveness of "export push". But it is quick to point out that policy interventions need to be carried out within well-defined limits so as to keep price distortions mild. In contrast, revisionists place stress on the specific (and selective) promotion approach with attendant specific policy measures and institutional arrangements. The latter would claim that import liberalisation and deregulation of FDI have been realised, in most cases, specifically to promote export rather than as part of general policy orientation. Ex post statistical indicators might indicate reduced overall levels of distortions, they would argue, but that is nothing more than an artifact of statistical aggregation, and no meaningful policy lesson should be drawn from that. There seems to be more agreement on the understanding that, if specific policies were in fact significant in East Asia, it is largely due to the good institutional underpinnings, both of a general and a specific nature.

The experience of specific policy approaches in Africa has been rather bleak. Harrold et al. (1996) investigate a number of African countries experiences with export promotion schemes. It is worth quoting their conclusion:

"Export development policies have been a critical part of East Asia’s success and merit consideration. These schemes, mainly duty exemption and drawback systems have failed in Sub-Saharan Africa for reasons of trust and capacity, cumbersome procedures, and because the cost from delays and paperwork outweigh the reduction in duty". (p. 80)

This rigerous prerequisties for a successful selective strategy (as identified earlier) raise important issues regarding the advisability of specific policy approaches and for the design and implementation of an adequate policy mix. It also suggests that the institutional foundations behind successful promotion schemes are critical. In the next two sections we will discuss each of these institutional quadrants in turn.

V. Institutional Foundations of External Performance

The work of North (see for example, 1990) and Coase (see for example, 1992) have been instrumental in advancing understanding of the influence of institutions on growth. The starting point is similar to neoclassical economics in that it takes economic actors to act as rational maximising atomistic agents. Institutions provide the structure of exchange that determines the cost of transactions (North, 1990: 34). They can improve the levels of investment and growth by processing information, reducing uncertainty and reducing transaction costs.

Institutional analysis can thus provide a tool that is useful in furthering understanding and in generating policy recommendations. One of the main advantages of institutional analysis is that it incorporates both the state and markets as institutions that shape the nature of economic activities. There can be little argument that states provide the environment within which economic activity occurs. In this regard the state can make both a positive contribution and a negative contribution.

Based on Weder (1997) classify institutions into four levels. Some of the key questions are also outlined.

  • Political Level - Commitment and credibility - the need to take a long-term perspective, to set objectives and build a reputation for achieving them. To what extent are states committed to an outward oriented strategy?
  • Public level – institutions for an efficient and non-corrupt bureaucracy. Issues raised in the literature refer to merit-based recruitment and promotion, adequate wages for civil servants, elite central agencies, transparency and accountability, insulation from political pressures and control mechanisms. To what extent do these exist in the government agencies responsible for external linkages?
  • Public- Private level – a bureaucracy that is closely connected to but still independent of the business community What is the relationship between government agencies responsible for external linkages and private sector agents? Is this one of bureaucratic discretion and rent seeking or information sharing and participation? What are the main factors mediating the relationship?
  • Level of Private Agents – importance of basic property and contractual rights; the level of fraud; the effectiveness of "agencies of restraint". What is the status of property rights relating to international and international-oriented agents and of international transactions?

What is the empirical evidence on the quality of institutions in East Asia and in Africa? The difficulty in answering this question stems from the difficulty in measuring institutional quality. There are a few measures of institutional quality, mostly based on surveys of either experts or of the private sector. For instance, Borner, Brunetti and Weder (1995) propose an indicator of the credibility of rules based on surveys. The survey was designed to capture local entrepreneurs’ views of the predictability of changes in laws and policies, of the reliability of law enforcement, of the impact of discretionary and corrupt bureaucracies and of the danger of policy reversals due to changes in governments. This indicator and its various components were included in standard cross-country growth and investment regressions leading to the finding that low credibility of rules lowers investment and growth. Table 9 shows the results of the credibility indicator for few East Asian and African countries.

Table 9: to be added

This summary indicator confirms that South East Asian countries have performed very well in terms of institutional quality, while African countries have tended to have institutions which were not conducive to private sector development. The next two subsections discuss some general and specific institutions for successful integration.

5.1. General institutions for external performance

As mentioned above, the general institutions for external performance are not different from the institutional preconditions that have been identified for general private sector development. Table 7 mentioned a few such exemplary general institutional conditions: secure property rights, a reliable judiciary, rule of law, high capability in the bureaucracy, competent core economic agencies and political commitment to development.

The difference in the level of political commitment to development between East Asia and Africa is often highlighted. A rough definition of this commitment would be the willingness to risk political capital in order to achieve growth. The regimes in Malaysia and Indonesia (this also holds for Thailand if the monarchy is included) have also been more stable. Therefore these countries had leaders in power for long periods that placed economic growth as a top priority. The regimes in Southeast Asia have been willing to shield top economic planning agencies in the bureaucracy from political pressures and to follow their policy advice. The key lessons seems to be "to give priority to and insulate from political interference, the functions of macro-economic management and long term development strategy" (Widner, 1994).

The weak institutional foundations for growth in Africa is probably most visible in the political sphere. Many attribute one of the primary causes for Africa's development tragedy to the predatory nature of African states. African governments, have tended not to be able to put long term national development priorities over more immediate political or personal ones. Similarly, Collier and Gunning (1997) conclude that: "African governments have behaved in ways which are damaging to the long term interests of the majority of their populations because they have served narrow constituencies." The instability of regimes has also been higher. It is worrying that commentators still not that despite the rhetoric African leaders still seem to have a mistrust of the private sector (Adams, 1998).

In addition to political commitment, a much discussed institutional foundation of Southeast Asian countries’s success are their relatively competent and efficient bureaucracies. Clientalistic, rent-seeking behaviour exists in both regions but the key difference is that Southeast Asian countries tended to keep rent-seeking within bounds or have managed to grow rapidly despite this. In this context, one of the clearest lessons to emerge from the East Asian experience is the value of merit-based recruitment and promotion practices for fostering a capable and motivated civil service. Adequate compensation of civil servants was used in order to attract and retain capable staff and merit based promotion practices have ensured relatively efficient performance of the bureaucracy. To foster internal controls and restraints, some countries also introduced specific control mechanism and watchdog organisation, such as anti-corruption commissions.

At the public level, Reynolds (1995) notes that government’s administrative competence is the single most important factor explaining the difference in growth among many developing countries. In contrast to Southeast Asia, African governments have often been more preoccupied with securing public employment than promoting the quality of the civil service. Positions in public sector institutions, including many parastatals and monitoring and regulatory agencies, have been made ineffective due to political appointments, politically controlled funding and multiple objectives. Transparency and accountability of these public institutions has been minimal. Africa comes in the bottom group in cross-regional comparison in terms of an index of "bureaucratic efficiency" (Adam and O'Connell 1997). Even in the face of fiscal pressure, public employment was often maintained and even expanded at lower levels of the bureaucracy. The World Bank put it quite starkly: "[African] governments have become employers of last resort and dispensers of political patronage, offering jobs to family, friends and supporters" (The World Bank, 1997: 95). The poor economic management capacity and cumbersome administrative and bureaucratic structures of African bureaucracies has limited the successful formulation and implementation of economic policies and become a central obstacle to market oriented reforms.

There is universal agreement on the great need to improve the management of African economies. Reflecting the experience with technical assistance, Dia (1996) advances the debate greatly. He finds that the incentives that determine behaviour are as important as training and resources. He therefore distinguishes between two different types of capacity building.

  1. supply side – technical – Does a country have the staff, equipment and knowledge? If not, the solution is one of increasing the quantity and quality of education and training. This was the major problem after independence but is no longer considered as the key constraint.
  2. demand side – institutional – Does a country have the ability to make optimal use of existing resources. This involves issues such as commitment of leaders, enforceability of rules, local ownership & legitimacy, accountability, stability, incentives. He argues that this institutional side is the weakest link in Africa’s capacity building efforts.

This would seem to reflect the experience of economic management in Thailand and Indonesia, which was achieved with a few highly qualified economists. But the key is to insulate them from the political pressures that would undermine development-oriented policies and to provide the correct incentives and penalties to encourage their performance.

Also in terms of rule of law, many countries in Sub-Saharan Africa have certainly lacked the conditions for private sector development. For instance, the survey conducted for the 1997 World Development Report shows that formal enforcement of property and contract rights are indeed a problem. Between 70 and 80 percent of entrepreneurs answered that they thought that theft and crime were serious problems, that they were not confident that the state authorities would protect their persons and property and that judiciaries were very unpredictable.

5.2. Specific institutions and external performance

Regarding institutions specifically affecting integration, these tend to reflect the application of general institutional issues to the external sector issues. For example, at the political level, this would refer to, for example, the political commitment to increasing exports. Other such issues are identified by Harrold et al. (1996) in their study of Southeast Asian trade and industrialisation lessons for Africa. These include issues such as the existence of a competent economic bureaucracy, that bureaucrats and private sector actors should enjoy a high degree of mutual respect and that there should be a minimum of trust between the government and the private sector. First we will discuss two specific institutional mechanisms for export promotion, which have been studied in the East Asian context: (i) a clear political commitment for exports and (ii) deliberation councils. We will then look more closely at some of the specific institutions in Sub Saharan Africa.

The political commitment of Southeast Asian leaders and elites to economic development has often been noted. This commitment was usually credible because the leaders’ personal incentives appeared to be in line with the announced course of action. Moreover they had specific commitment for promoting development though encouraging exports. One instrument of this commitment was a quantitative export target. A target alone is of course not sufficient to increase export, but they were backed up with concrete policy measures as discussed above, and with some institutional arrangements. The most famous of these are the so-called business councils.

Most East Asian governments have worked very closely with the business community to achieve specific development goals. They have built forums on which government officials and industry representatives discussed and designed policies for external performance. The most famous such forum is the business council or deliberation council. The main function of the council is to gain information that is needed to formulate policies that will enhance the performance of the private sector. At the same time the deliberation council may help to reduce rent seeking through a more transparent allocation of rents and also helps to reduce uncertainty about future policies. The Korean government used government-business forums for the implementation of export policies by setting specific performance standards were set for private firms, which were monitored and adjusted according to market conditions.

In Africa, the relationship between the government and the private sector has been much more adversarial than in East Asia, both in general and with specific reference to trans-national corporations. There has also been in many cases a lack of political commitment to integration, particularly in the years after independence, reflecting concerns about neo-imperialism. A small, recent example of different levels of political commitment to integration is that of the approaches taken by Uganda and Kenya toward the Forum on Trade and Investment in Africa held in Addis Ababa in March 1998. Uganda sent the President and Minister of Trade, gaining much credibility in the process. Kenya sent the Vice-Chairman of a Manufacturers Association with the opposite result (reported in the Daily Nation, 1998).

The experience of some African countries with versions of deliberation councils has generally not been so positive. Deliberation councils need a substantial technical capability if they are to use the information supplied effectively. Also they have the inherent problem that, by default, they exclude some parts of the private sector and can well degenerate into mechanisms for unproductive rent extraction by the insiders.

This list of factors shows the close interaction between general and specific institutions for successful external performance. For example, most of the reasons why deliberation councils failed to deliver the same result in Africa as they did in Asia are related to a lack of general institutional foundations. It seems that at least some of the general institutional basis must be in place to ensure private sector development.

VI. Comparison of Key Issues

The conference will concentrate on four main issues:

  • Resource Exports and Resource-processing for Export
  • Export oriented industrialisation and FDI
  • Management of Financial Flows
  • Management of Foreign Aid and Debt

This section provides a brief comparative overview of each of these in turn.

6.1. Resource Exports and Resource-Processing for Export

There is a general pessimism about dependence on primary exports in terms of a long term development strategy. Also, due to the emphasis on manufacturing in literature on East Asia, the importance of primary sector exports seems to have been underplayed. However a number of studies have found that the expansion of primary exports was one of the key factors behind the integration of Southeast Asia (Tomich et al., 1994; Chhibber and Leechor, 1995). In Southeast Asia the expansion of primary exports seems, through the mechanisms indicated in the Box below, to have had a significant impact on the development. The rapid growth of agricultural exports in Malaysia, Indonesia and Thailand was also a basis for the subsequent upgrading and shift to manufacturing (Chhibber and Leechor, 1995). In this regard it is important to recognise that primary exports remain the most important link to the global economy for many countries in sub-Saharan Africa. Any strategy for increasing Africa’s linkages to the global economy will need to centre initially on resource exports.

The primary export performance of Southeast Asia and Africa has differed markedly. Again a rough contrast is that the primary export base shrank in African countries between 1970 and 1990 whereas it was maintained in Southeast Asia despite the shift to manufacturing (Tomich et al., 1994). Successes have been seen in coffee and tea in Kenya and cocoa in Cote D’Ivoire in Africa, for example, but these have not been sustained. Overall, it is telling that African countries failed to maintain their market shares of in the commodities in which they had a comparative advantage whereas Southeast Asian countries have been gaining export shares in the same markets previously dominated by Africa and Latin America.

There is widespread agreement that one of the key factors behind the successful agricultural exporters in Southeast Asia was that they maintained exchange rates that favor exporters. Tomich et al (1994) also identified three main areas of heavy investment that supported export agriculture: rural transportation, research and planting programs. These increased yields and reduce the costs of growing exportable crops.

Finally, there is interesting evidence on the constraints faced by firms trying to move into non-traditional exporting in East Africa (Ndulu, Semboja and Mbelle, 1998 and Mwega, 1998). A summary of the findings of four surveys of the constraints faced by firms in the liberalisation era– see Appendix 4. The key restrictions were identified as:

  • Lack of finance
  • Inadequate supportive infrastructure (e.g. transport, power, water, waste disposal, telephones, storage at ports)
  • Bureaucracy and an adverse regulatory environment.

As one of the studies emphasises, it is the general influences that played a more important role in export promotion than specific policy measures (Bol, 1995).

The key question for Africa is (i) how can primary exports be expanded; (ii) whether primary export expansion is a pre-requisite or if a shift to manufacturing can be achieved in other ways?

6.2. Export-oriented Industrialisation and FDI

The strong relationship between industrialisation and economic development indicates a vital need to look at this issue. Linked to export promotion and encouraging inward investment, the rapid rate of industrialisation was one of the cornerstones of the strong performance of Southeast Asia. Accounting for this also remains one of the most contentious issues for analysis. In contrast, there has been very little upgrading in most countries in Africa. The share of primary commodities in total African exports only declined marginally - from 92% in 1965 to 86% in 1987 (Wangwe, 1995). Only very few countries have been able to export manufactured products.

The difference in manufactured export performance between Southeast Asia and selected countries in Africa is highlighted in Graphs 7. It shows that the proportion of manufactures in exports were relatively similar in Southeast Asia and Africa in 1970, in some cases African countries were markedly better off. However, since then there has been a rapid and sustained increase in the proportion of manufactured exports in all three countries in Southeast Asia. In Africa, there has not been much increase except for Mauritius, where it was even more pronounced than in SE Asia.

Source: Calculated from World Development Indicators, 1997.

A similar picture emerges if we compare FDI. Both regions were attracting low levels of FDI in the 1970s. Since then Southeast Asia has attracted increasing amounts of FDI whereas many countries in Africa attract virtually no inward investment. The year 1987 is a key turning point where Southeast Asia began to attract large amounts of FDI after the Plaza Accord.

It is interesting to note that Malaysia really stands out as the country where FDI is likely to have had the most significant impact. FDI accounted for an increasing proportion of GDP and investment (see Appendix 3) whereas the impact of FDI was more limited in other countries. In Thailand for example, Thai corporate investment was twelve times that of all foreign investment (Phongpaichit and Baker, 1998). It must be noted that FDI may be of a greater qualitative value (vis a vis upgrading) than domestic investment.

Source: Calculated from World Development Indicators, 1997.

The share of Africa in FDI flows to all developing countries dropped from c6% to c3% between 1984-89 and 1994-95 (World Bank, 1997b). The explanation for low FDI flows to Africa include factors such as civil conflict, low GDP growth, low trade openness and high variability of real effective exchange rates. In terms of enhancing FDI potential in Africa, recent studies emphasise a number of institutional issues. These (see UNCTAD, 1995; Pearce, Islam and Sauvant, 1996) include:

  • reduce bureaucratic procedures and assure property rights;
  • treat foreign and domestic investors equally;
  • establish efficient (low rate) tax systems;
  • ease access to foreign exchange and expatriate employment

Overall, a key point that seems to be emerging is that it is "systemic competetiveness" that will affect the amount of investment that is attracted. The issues firms would look for include:

  • Sound economic policies
  • Social concerns – education, health, languages, non-fragmented societies, non-confrontational culture
  • Labour skills
  • Physical infrastructure
  • Rule of law
  • Efficient and effective public sector

Source: Rodriguez, 1998

6.3. Management of Financial Flows

Although the level of financial flows to sub-Saharan Africa remains relatively small, there are two main reasons for focusing on this issue. First, one of the key conduits of globalisation is through cross-border transactions of financial assets. Second, this financial linkage, particularly its high volatility, has major implications for macroeconomic stability as well as on real sector performances, as vividly witnessed in the most recent currency crisis experienced by the three Southeast Asian economies. The importance of a strong financial system is one of key lessons of Asian crisis that is valid for all developing countries.

Graph 9 clearly contrast the level of capital inflows of selected countries in Southeast Asia and Africa. Southeast Asian countries have shown a greater ability to attract capital flows after low inflows in 1970. The explosive growth of such flows to their level in 1995 is notable. Similarly notable is the total inability of African countries to attract finance. For much of Africa, there needs to be concentration on policy and institutions that provide an attractive environment that can reverse capital flight rather than to control excessive inflows.

Source: Calculated from World Development Indicators, 1997.

6.4. ODA, Debt and Development

In overall terms, private financial flows to developing countries are now substantially greater than official flows of foreign aid. But, financial flows are concentrated in a few countries and of importance to this study is the fact that foreign aid remains one of the most significant external links for much of sub-Saharan Africa. There is a great need to reduce aid dependence and increase the effectiveness of aid in Africa. There is also a great need to resolve the debt problem facing many countries in Africa. In contrast, countries in Southeast Asia seem to have managed foreign aid and debt effectively, thereby accelerating the development process. There may be interesting lessons for Africa in this regard.

Graph 10 shows the proportion of ODA to GNP for select countries in Southeast Asia and Africa. The low levels in Southeast Asia (and Mauritius) contrast markedly with the high and rising levels in the other countries in Africa. Although the data is rather scarce, Graph 11 gives an indication of the level of dependence on ODA of African governments. African countries now seem caught in an low-level trap of "aid dependence" whereby aid is vital for the short term yet is distracting countries away from concentrating more on the more dynamic issue for long-term development – fostering the private sector.

Source: Calculated from World Development Indicators, 1997.

Unfortunately, the current ODA situation in Africa can probably most accurately be described as a bit of a mess. In a recent review of aid performance in Africa, Helleiner (1998) concludes that as it is practised at present aid remains a "wholly unsatisfactory basis for linking Africa with the world …. The impact of ODA is constrained by procurement restrictions and conditions unrelated to development, high transaction costs and poor donor co-ordination……. Aid would have to be massively transformed if it were to serve as a major instrument for mediating Africa’s future relationship with the world" (Helleiner, 1998). It seems unlikely, however, that a transformation will take place and aid flows are declining in any case.

Source: Calculated from World Development Indicators, 1997.

It is clear that central responsibility for aid effectiveness and aid co-ordination lies with each recipient (World Bank, 1995). In contrast to Southeast Asia (see Soderberg, 1996) very few recipient countries in Africa have put forward a coherent development strategy and have demonstrated the ability to co-ordinate aid flows around this. But this partly reflects the incentive structure facing recipients that donors have created.

There seems to be a strong argument that better selectivity of countries is the key to aid effectiveness in Africa or elsewhere. In terms of our framework outlined above, most aid can basically be considered as a specific intervention. And similar to other specific measures it would seem to be more likely to be effective if sound general economic policy and institutional foundations exist. Similar to developing country governments being warned away from specific policy unless very rigerous conditions are met, it would seem that donors should have to meet similarly stringent conditions in choosing the countries they provide aid to. But what are the most useful objective criteria for selectivity and monitoring? First, there is certainly increasing evidence that aid works better in a good policy environment (Dollar, 1996). In this regard, the general economic policy criteria outlined in the previous sections could be used. Second, there would also seem to be a good case for including institutional criteria – political commitment, bureaucratic quality, rule of law, property rights etc. Clearly, more work is needed in identifying viable criteria in this area.

On the issue of debt, the constraint on development imposed by the debt overhand is increasingly clear, particularly for Africa. In their regression analysis Ndulu and Ndungu (1997) find a very strong negative and significant influence of the debt to GDP ratio beyond a threshold of 97% - a very large proportion of African counties exceed this threshold and face retardation of growth. Easing the burden of unsustainable debt would free up government resources for more productive developmental activities, reduce transactions costs (which are a massive burden on policy-makers) and help restore macroeconomic stability and investor confidence. A dollar of reduced debt is therefore likely to be more valuable than an additional dollar of conventional aid. Thus Helleiner concludes that there is "an overwhelming intellectual case for significant further reductions in the external debt of debt-distressed-low income countries in Africa, and particularly if the resources made available are truly additional." But debt relief, like aid in general, is only likely to have a significant impact if recipient governments have sound policy and institutional fundamentals in place.

VII. The Transferability of Lessons?

One of the main aims of the project is to take a close look at the key issue of the transferability of any lessons between Southeast Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa. Successful economic policies and institutional arrangements need to be rooted in the underlying structures and characteristics of each country. Although many are sceptical about the potential for drawing lessons from Northeast Asia for Africa, as argued above, we feel that Southeast Asia and Africa may be similar enough for there to be the potential to draw lessons from Southeast Asia for countries in Africa. It is also important to reflect on whether external circumstances have changed significantly enough to affect transferability.

But, first it is important to outline what we mean by transferability. We do not mean the direct wholesale adoption of economic policies or institutional arrangements. Instead, we refer to indigenous adaptation (the alteration of ideas to suit local circumstances) and to proximate institutional prerequisites. For example, economic policies should only be adopted where the technical capacity exists to implement them effectively or they should be adapted to suit the current capacity. This modification is even more important for transferring institutional arrangements. Copying Asian institutional arrangements should only be attempted if, for example, there is already sound macro-economic conditions, the appropriate social pre-conditions exist and/or if political commitment exists to ensure the credibility of any new institutional forms. If not, any arrangements would need to be modified to reflect the existing historical, cultural, economic and political context. But, as in other areas, latecomers do have the advantage of learning what has worked and what has not worked in other countries.

In this section we next identify some of the important differences between Southeast Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa in terms of socio-economic structures, domestic conditions and external circumstances.

7.1. Socio-economic Structures

Perkins and Roemer (1994) do an interesting comparison of socio-economic structures in Southeast Asia in the 1960s and Africa in the 1990s – see below. For most indicators there is a similarity in economic structure between Southeast Asia in 1965 and Africa in 1990. Many countries in Africa would actually have more favourable socio-economic structures now than Indonesia had in 1965. This would seem to suggest that African countries could achieve the kinds of results achieved in Southeast Asia. But, a key difference is in the level of savings which is was almost twice as high in Southeast Asia. Another difference is that adult illiteracy is notably higher in Africa in 1990 than in Asia in the 1965.

Table 4: Africa in 1990 and Southeast Asia in 1965.

Africa 1990

SE Asia 1965

Indonesia

Malaysia

Thailand

GDP

(US$)

658

868

461

1309

833

Agriculture share GDP

(%)

35.3

37.0

51

28

32

Manufacturing share of GDP

(%)

11.5

10.3

8

9

14

Savings share of GDP

(%)

8.7

17.0

8

24

19

Investment share of GDP

(%)

18.1

16.0

8

20

20

Export share of GDP

(%)

23.5

24.3

13

41

19

Urban population

(%)

27.9

18.3

16

26

13

Primary Education

(% of eligible population)

71.4

80.0

72

90

78

Secondary Education

(% of eligible population)

17.6

18.0

12

28

14

Adult Illiteracy

(% of adult population)

53

35.3

43

42

21

Life Expectancy

(years)

50.7

52.7

44

58

56

Source: Perkins and Roemer, 1996: 52.

However, historians argue that social science explanations have not been sufficient to answer the question "Why have some states been applying better economic policies than others?" (Thompson, 1998) and that there are "deeper differences among peoples environments", (Diamond, 1998). One factor often mentioned is that the type of colonisation in Africa was more destructive and reduced the ability of African states to respond to the opportunities after independence. Thompson (1998) tends to reject this argument, focusing instead on the advantages Southeast Asia had in terms of physical geography (easier environment, better natural resources and lower barriers to movement) and the access to ideas contained in the strategic location of Southeast Asia between China and India. In particular, Thompson concludes that "Southeast Asian cultures were better equipped to respond to the challenges and opportunities of the colonial era and, subsequently, to enter the capitalist, interconnected world of today".

Although the question posed by Thompson is very valid, the answer provided seems less convincing. The data shows that Southeast Asia and sub-Saharan Africa had similar economic situations (in per capita GDP, agriculture as a % of GDP, etc.) in the 1960s – why did this historical legacy favouring Southeast Asia not appear as such an advantage earlier? The argument also seems to rule out any form of action – that your development depends on factors outside your control. This seems to contradict much of the apparent evidence that successful performances were built not bequeathed. In other words, the analysis does not actually answer the key question about how these environmental issues actually led the state to apply better economic policies in Southeast Asia than Africa.

The analysis by Thompson does however raise questions about the limits of economic statistics in capturing the crucial factors that affect successful economic performance in a globalising world. Our analysis has tried to go beyond economic policy analysis and concentrate on the institutional foundations. This may provide more of the answer to the question of why have Southeast Asian countries and cultures been better at responding to the challenges and opportunities that emerged since the 1960s. A key point for further investigation is: How similar were the institutional starting points? And what are the key factors affecting these?

7.2. Human Resources

One of the main issues that is usually discussed regarding the replicability of East Asian strategies is the endowment of human resources. If we look at the level of human resources, Africa certainly had a disadvantage compared to Southeast Asia in the 1960s, when Southeast Asian countries had began their primary export expansion. Even compared to Indonesia, which had the lowest endowments in Southeast Asia in the 1960s, Africa started from a weak position. This is illustrated in Graphs 12 and 13 using primary and secondary enrolment as indicators.

The graphs indicate that both regions have made rapid progress. The average for Africa in 1990 is equivalent to that of Indonesia in 1965. But this masks a great disparity within Africa, as indicated by a comparison of Kenya with Burkina Faso for example. The Africa Brief (World Bank, 1998) is very clear on this: "In education, Africa faces an alarming deficit: 15 countries (out of 48) still enroll less than half of their children in primary school; 25 countries have adult literacy rates below 40%; less than 4% of the relevant age-group has access to higher education; and more than half of all African women are illiterate. Further, enrollment rates are dropping." This has very important implications in terms of recommending for many (but not all) countries in Africa the types of approach undertaken by East Asia (e.g. upgrading into manufacturing) and for transferring institutional arrangements.

Source: Calculated from World Development Indicators, 1997.

Source: Calculated from World Development Indicators, 1997.

7.3. External Circumstances

There are a number of specific differences in external circumstances that seem to indicate potential hurdles to African countries in an attempt to imitate some of the Southeast Asian policies.

  • First, there is the perception that the global economy is now characterised by increased competition due to the number of countries attempting "export-oriented" strategies. However, the "fallacy of composition" argument can be challenged because of the experience that export oriented strategies tend also to generate imports.
  • Second, the levels of debt in Africa are much higher than they were in Southeast Asia. Debt service payments are now claiming 30-40% of Africa’s export earnings. These payments are also larger than government expenditures for health and education. It is increasingly accepted that the debt crisis represents one of the most constraining factors for recovery and growth in sub-Saharan Africa. A key question for investigation is: To what extent does the current debt crisis limit the options African countries have regarding strategies for integration?
  • Third, African countries are unlikely to be able to pursue some of the policies undertaken by Southeast Asian countries due to the extent to which IFI’s dominate policy-making. The World Bank and to a greater degree the IMF do not have a favourable view of undertaking selective policies in Africa.
  • Fourth, and in a similar vein, there is a perception that the policies undertaken by the Southeast Asian countries would no longer be permitted in the new global trading environment as represented by the World Trade Organization. An analysis by UNCTAD staff (see Akyuz et al., 1997) found, however, that although the WTO has reduced the scope for some policy options it will not restrict poorer countries to a considerable degree.

There is also a temporal and strategic dimension to the question of the transferability of policy and institutional lessons for improving external performance – i.e. concerning the nature of "globalisation". First, the extent of globalisation is likely to be different now than in the past. Also, although the process of globalisation in the world economy that has been progressing for many decades, centuries even, it could be argued first that the process is becoming qualitatively different. Global economic interaction is becoming increasingly electronic / financial rather than physical, with the global economy increasingly information-based rather than industrial. Second, and linked to this, it seems that the pace of globalisation has accelerated. The relevance of past experiences needs to be examined in this context.

The strategic dimension is that the evolving situation could offer the strategic opportunity for African countries to leapfrog stages of development. This has the added incentive for Africa that a knowledge-based economy is based on a cheap resource (silicon) and entails lower initial investments compared to industrialisation (Ndulu, 1998). But, such a strategy would put a premium on very high levels of human capital and on developing infrastructure to link to global information networks. Apart from South Africa, there seem to be few countries in Africa that could consider such a strategy.

VIII. Summary and Preliminary Conclusions (to be updated)

Given the rapid rates of economic growth in East and Southeast Asia over the last three decades there has been considerable effort devoted to investigating the causes of this performance. Although economic growth has slowed in Southeast Asia is in recent months "the crisis does not take away from the achievements of history". Africa can benefit from the lessons of the successful Southeast Asian experiences as well as the lessons contained in the current crisis. It can also learn from the lessons of its own economic history.

Most countries in Africa are small and poor, making an inward looking strategy unattractive. Significant advances in economic development in Africa in the future will depend in no small part on the success with which countries can exploit the opportunities and avoid the risks presented by globalisation. A viable outward oriented strategy for countries in Africa will have to reflect the structure of the economy and endowments relative to other parts of the world. On the first point, the primary sector dominates most economies in Africa. On the second, Africa has low levels of human capital in comparison to other regions. The familiar proposition seems to hold – for most countries in Africa comparative advantage lies in primary production and unskilled labour-intensive primary processing (Perkins and Roemer, 1994; Wood 1994; Helleiner, 1998). Given the long gestation period of investments in human capital, this is likely to remain the situation for many years to come.

This section intends to bring some of the major themes together in order to suggest a few preliminary conclusions as well as highlighting further questions. The conclusions will naturally need to be amended based on the findings of the conference. It must also be stressed again that circumstances vary within Africa and only broad conclusions can be made at this stage.

8.1. Broad Policy Messages for Africa

The main message that seems to emerge is that in order to integrate more successfully into the global economy countries in Africa will need to concentrate on improving the general economic policy and institutional situation. In this regard, it is important to reiterate three broad conclusions. (Some related follow-up questions are added).

  1. The importance of sound "general" economic policies
  2. These include investment in human and physical capital, a stable macroeconomic environment and greater outward orientation. These were the basis for Southeast Asia’s performance. In particular, analyses indicate that many countries in Africa still not have the macro-economic policy stance that would enable them to maximise their external performance. (What kind of "targets" can be set in this regard?) In particular, there is still a need to reduce anti-export bias. However, sound general policies seem a necessary but not a sufficient foundation; although policy stances have improved considerably in Africa, export and growth performances remain fragile.

  3. The importance of improving "general" institutional foundations
  4. Rather than technical capacity building, the key would seem to be, through reform, to improve the general institutional foundations. Surveys indicate that many countries in Africa do not have "adequate" institutional foundations for growth. In this regard, the key institutional foundations to aim for are political commitment and credibility, an efficient and non-corrupt bureaucracy; a degree of bureaucratic insulation from political pressures, a positive relationship between government / bureaucracy and the private sector and basic property and contractual rights. (What kind of "targets" can be identified in this regard?) In particular, there is a real need for a balanced approach to the state – a strategy to strengthen the capacity to undertake important functions as well as to reduce unnecessary or negative aspects. It is likely that establishing sound institutional foundations will represent the greatest challenge for Africa for many years to come.

  5. The importance of matching policy choices with institutional capability

The key recommendation is to concentrate scarce institutional capability on the most important development priorities. For most countries in Africa, this means that the state should focus on the tasks outlined in points 1 and 2 above.

Specific policies do seem in some cases to have improved the level and nature of integration with the global economy. Given the lack of general foundations, most African counties would be ill advised, however, to pursue specific policies. It is unlikely that a specific policy or institutional measure will work if the general ones are unfavourable. In terms of a selective export oriented strategy very few countries come close to satisfying the conditions outlined by Lall (1997). (What kind of "targets" can be identified regarding the necessary conditions to make these policies successful in Africa?) In African countries with adequate policy and institutional foundations, some of the lessons from Southeast Asia could be considered. The most important of these (and probably most easily replicable) are the "export push" strategies pursued by Malaysia, Indonesia and Thailand. In most countries, it would seem that these should be concentrated on the primary sector and focus on issues such as creating or supporting institutions for research and development, education and training and infrastructure. These should be limited in scope, based on objective performance criteria and time bound.

8.2 Cross–cutting Issues for Clarification

a) Economic Policies

Neoclassical economists have long propounded the general approach to openness. According to such analysis, taking the sphere of trade as an example, openness provides the potential to exploit comparative advantage and economies of scale as well as the opportunity for the greater utilisation of capacity. In addition, competitive pressure can lead to increased efficiency. There is also the argument that productivity increases are associated more with inputs acquired via importing and that productivity gains are generated as global technical change continues (World Bank, 1991). Since the 1980s the Bretton Woods Institutions have applied this approach as basic tenet of structural adjustment policies emphasising the importance of across-the-board liberalisation. Recently a series of empirical works based on growth regressions (see for example, Sachs and Warner, 1995) have been conducted to provide support for this position.

In contrast, aiming towards strategic integration would imply that countries should liberalise in order to gain the benefits outlined above but only when and up to a point that it is in the national interest to do so. This is based on the arguments regarding "dynamic" comparative advantages, learning by doing and that imperfect competition exists in the real world (Singh, 1994). Chakravarty and Singh (1988) argue first that openness is a multi-dimensional concept (incorporating, among other things, trade, finance, technology and migration). The argument runs that circumstances vary according to each aspect, therefore the optimal level of openness may differ for each aspect and therefore a country should operate a different policy for each sphere. Second, their analysis suggests that that there is no single optimum form or degree of openness, which holds true for all countries all the time. The factors that affect the particular degree of openness would include, for example, the world configuration, the past history of the economy and its state of development (Singh, 1994). The question is not only about how much to liberalise but about what is the best policy mix to achieve integration. Aiming towards strategic integration also involves a more proactive approach by the state through a measured and properly sequenced set of policies towards trade, capital flows and FDI (Akyuz et al., 1997). Strategic interventions would involve short-terms costs, which would be discounted for longer-term gain (although even strategic interventions should see results relatively quickly).

The challenge is that the evidence is not conclusive. It does not clearly support either that liberal trade regimes always leads to greater productivity increases or that strategic government polices necessarily have such effects. Based on the lack of clear evidence and the poor institutional quality in most countries in the region, the standard advice is that it would seem to be safer for these countries to go for the liberalization option. This leaves a number of key questions for Africa:

  • What is the relationship between the scale of policy liberalisation and the scale and forms integration?
  • Can and do standard market based (thus general) economic policies for integration have limited impact for long term – e.g. they could result in static comparative advantage associated with declining (and volatile) income streams and hence low-level traps.
  • Is there a case for different approaches to liberalisation in the different spheres of integration? What are some of the key issues (regulation capacity etc) that should underly degree of liberalisation in each sphere?

b) Institutional Foundations:

We hope the conference will generate further insights into (i) the general institutional foundations for improving external performance and (ii) the specific foundations in each sphere identified. This sections highlights one further proposal - the setting up a cross-cutting "competetiveness promotion" agency would be one way countries could start to link these issues. Lall (1998) identifies that most developing countries are not geared to mounting an export competetiveness strategy because most decisions affecting exports are scattered over an array of ministries and institutions. He argues that to increase competetiveness there is a need for an agency that can co-ordinate a strategy that cuts across competing interests and uses resources in each ministry to further national aims. It would need to be headed by high level minister or President and report directly to cabinet. The premise of this project is that globalisation entails a number of interlinked processes involving trade, FDI and finance – therefore the mandate of such an agency could be expanded to include all these facets. A similar kind of agency could be advocated for aid co-ordination.

References (to be updated)

Adam and O'Connell 1997 - ??

Adams, J., 1998, Africa and the World Bank, Comments in a presentation at the FASID seminar on Economic Prospects for Africa on 10 July 1998.

Akyuz, Y., Chang, H. and Kozul-Wright, R., 1997, New Perspectives on East Asian Development, UNCTAD discussion paper.

Aron, J., 1997, The Institutional Foundations of Growth, in Ellis, S. (ed.) Africa Now: People, Policies, Institutions, The Hague: DGIS.

Blackhurst R. and Lyakurwa, W., 1997, Markets and Market Access for African Exports, Paper presented at AERC workshop on Africa and the WTO, November 1997.

Bol, 1995, ??

Borner, S., Brunetti, A. and Weder, B., 1995, Political Credibility and Economic Development.

Brunetti Aymo, Gregory Kisunko and Beatrice Weder (1997b): "Credibility of Rules and Economic Growth: Evidence from a Worldwide Survey of the Private Sector" (1997b), World Bank Policy Research Paper No. 1760, Washington DC: The World Bank

Calamitsis, E., 1998, Africa’s Economic Performance and Challenges and the Role of the IMF, Paper presented at the FASID seminar on Economic Prospects for Africa on 10 July 1998.

Campos, Jose Edgardo and Donald Lien (1994): Institutions and the East Asian Miracle: Asymmetric Information, Rent-Seeking and the Deliberations Council, Policy Research Working Paper No. 1321, Washington DC: The World Bank

Chakravarty, S. and Singh, A., 1988, The Desirable Forms of Economic Openness in the South, Mimeo Helsinki: UNU/WIDER.

Chang, Ha-Joon, 1997, Trade, Industry and Technology Policies in Northeast Asia, Paper presented at the AERC conference on Comparative Development Experiences in Asia and Africa, November 1997.

Chibber and Leechor, 1995, From Adjustment to Growth in sub-Saharan Africa: the Lessons from the East Asian Experience Applied to Ghana, Journal of African Economies, Vol. 4, No. 1, pp. 83-114.

Coase, R.H., 1992, ‘The Institutional Structure of Production’, American Economic Review, Vol. 28, No. 4, 713-720.

Collier, P., 1991, "Africa’s external economic relations: 1960-1990", in African Affairs, Vol. 90, pp. 339-356.

Collier, P., 1995, "The marginalisation of Africa", International Labour Review, Vol. 134 No 4-5.

Collier, P., 1997, "Policy Commitment Arrangements for Africa: Implications for Aid, Trade and Investment Flows", Paper presented at AERC workshop on Africa and the WTO, November 1997.

Collier and Gunning (1997) - ??

Court, J., 1998, Institutions and Economic Development in Africa, background paper for UNU project.

Daily Nation, 1998 - ??

Dia, M., 1996, Africa's Management in the 1990s and Beyond: Reconciling Indigenous and Transplanted Institutions, Washington DC: The World Bank.

Diamond, J., 1998, Guns, Germs and Steel: The Fates of Human Societies, Norton.

Dollar, 1996, ??, Washington DC: The World Bank.

Easterly, W. and Levine, R, (1995) Africa's Growth Tragedy: A Retrospective, August 1995, World Bank Working Paper 1503.

Elbadawi, I., Ndulu, B. and Ndung’u, N., 1997, Macroeconomic Performance in Sub-Saharan Africa in a Comparative Setting, Paper presented at the AERC conference on Comparative Development Experiences in Asia and Africa, November 1997.

Evans, P., 1997, Transferable lessons? Pr-examining the Institutional Prerequisites of East Asian Economic Policies, Unpublished manuscript.

Harriss, J., 1997, Africa and Southeast Asian Development Since 1960, Keynote paper presented at the Collaborative Research Project on Comparative African and East Asian Development Experiences Conference, Johannesburg, South Africa, November 1997.

Harrold, P., Jayawickrama, M. and Bhattasali, D., 1996, Practical Lessons for Africa from East Asia in Industrial and Trade Policies, World Bank Discussion Papers, Africa Technical Department Series, No. 310.

Helleiner, G., forthcoming, Africa in the Global Economy, mimeo.

Hill, H., 1996, The Indonesian Economy since 1966: Southeast Asia's Emerging Giant, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Ishikawa, S., 1997,

Jomo, K.S., 1997, Southeast Asia’s Misunderstood Miracle, Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press.

Knack, Stephen and Philip Keefer (1995): "Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures ", Economics and Politics 7, pp.207-227.

Lall, S., 1997, Selective Policies for Export Promotion: Lessons from the Asian Tigers, Paper presented at the UNU/WIDER project meeting in Kampala, Uganda on 16-18 June 1997.

Lindauer, D. and Roemer, M., (eds) 1994, Asia and Africa,: Legacies and Opportunities in Development, San Francisco: ISC Press.

Mwega, 1998, Kenya Case Study, Paper presented at the UNU/WIDER project meeting in Addis Ababa, Ethiopia on 16-20 March 1998.

Nabli, M. and Nugent, J., 1989, "The new institutional economics and its applicability to development, " World Development, Vol. 17, No. 9.

Ndulu, Semboja and Mbelle, 1998, Promoting Non-Traditional Exports in Tanzania, Paper presented at the UNU/WIDER project meeting in Addis Ababa, Ethiopia on 16-20 March 1998.

Ndulu, 1998, - ??

Ng, F. and Yeats, A., 1997, "Open economies work better! Did Africa’s protectionist policies cause its marginalisation in world trade?" in World Development, Vol. 25, No 6, pp. 889-904.

Nissanke, M and Aryeetey, E., 1997, Comparative Institutional Analysis: Sub-Saharan Africa and East Asia – Thematic Paper, Paper presented at the AERC conference on Comparative Development Experiences in Asia and Africa, November 1997.

North, D., 1990, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Ostry, S., 1997, The post-cold war trading system, Publisher?

Oyejide, A., 1997, Costs and benefits of "special and differential" treatment for developing countries in GATT/WTO: an African perspective, Paper presented at AERC workshop on Africa and the WTO, November 1997.

Pearce, Islam and Sauvant, 1996, ??

Perkins, D. and Roemer, M., 1994, Differing Endowments and Historical Legacies, in Lindauer, D. and Roemer, M., (eds) 1994, op cit.

Phongpaichit, P and Baker, C., 1998, Thailand’s Boom and Bust, Silkworm Books.

Reynolds, 1995 -??

Rodrik, D., 1997, Trade Policy and Economic Performance in Sub-Saharan Africa, ??

Rodriguez, E., 1998, Costa Rica: Policies and Conditions for Export Diversification, Paper presented at the UNU/WIDER project meeting in Addis Ababa, Ethiopia on 16-20 March 1998.

Sachs, J. and Warner, A., 1995, Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Washington: Brookings Institution.

Sachs, J. and Warner, A., 1996, Sources of Slow Growth in African Economies, July 1996. 12 pp. Harvard University Occasional Papers.

Singh, A., 1994, Openness and the market friendly approach to development in World Development, Vol. 22, No. 12, pp. 1811-1823.

Soderberg, M., 1996,

Stein, H. (ed.), 1994a, Asian Industrialisation and Africa: Studies in Policy Alternatives to Structural Adjustment, London: Macmillan.

Stein, H., 1994b, "Theories of institutions and economic reform in Africa," World Development, Vol. 22, No 12, pp. 889-904.

Stiglitz, J., 1998, Comments at UNU Public Forum on Aid Co-ordination on 22 June 1998.

Thompson, L., 1998, Why has Sub-Saharan Africa lagged so far behind Southeast Asia?, Paper presented at the Annual meeting of the Japan Association of African Studies, 30 May, Sakura, Japan.

Tomich, T., Roemer, M. and Vincent, J., 1994, Development from a Primary Export Base, in Lindauer, D. and Roemer, M., (eds) 1994, op cit.

UNCTAD, 1995, - ??

Wang Z., and Winters, A., 1997, Africa’s Role in Multilateral Trade Negotiations, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 1846.

Wangwe, S., (ed.), 1995, Exporting Africa. Technology, Trade and Industrialization in Sub-Saharan Africa, London and New York: Routledge.

Weder, Beatrice, 1997, Any Lessons from East Asia? A review of the literature on the East Asian Miracle, WWZ Discussion Paper No 77.

Widner, J.,1994, Reform Bargains: The Politics of Change, in Lindauer, D. and Roemer, M., (eds) 1994, op cit.

World Bank, 1991, World Development Report 1991, Washington DC: The World Bank.

World Bank, 1993, The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy, Washington DC: The World Bank.

World Bank, 1994, Adjustment in Africa: Reforms, Results, and the Road Ahead, Washington DC: The World Bank.

World Bank, 1995, World Development Report 1995, Washington DC: The World Bank.

World Bank, 1997, World Development Report 1997: The State in a Changing World, Washington DC: The World Bank.

World Bank, 1997b, Global Economic Prospects and the Developing Countries 1997, Washington DC: The World Bank.

World Bank, 1997, World Development Indicators CD Rom, Washington DC: The World Bank.

World Bank, 1998, World Bank Africa Brief 1998, World Bank Internet Homepage.

Appendix 1:

Source: Calculated from World Development Indicators, 1997.

Appendix 2: GDP and Export Growth Rates in Africa (average 1990-96)

Country
Equatorial Guinea
Uganda
Mozambique
Sudan
Mauritius
Lesotho
Botswana
Namibia
Ghana
Benin
Guinea
Mauritania
Guinea-Bissau
Ethiopia
Tanzania
Cape Verde
Nigeria
The Gambia
Malawi
Seychelles
Burkina Faso
Gabon
Mali
Swaziland
Kenya
Senegal
Côte d’Ivoire
Chad
Niger
São Tomé and Principe
Zimbabwe
Comoros
South Africa
Central African Republic
Madagascar
Republic of Congo
Zambia
Togo
Cameroon
Burundi
Angola
Sierra Leone
Democratic Republic of Congo
Rwanda


GDP

7.0
6.9
5.5
5.3
5.2
5.0
4.8
4.3
4.3
4.2
3.8
3.5
3.4
3.4
3.4
3.3
3.1
3.0
3.0
2.9
2.7
2.5
2.5
2.1
1.9
1.8
1.7
1.3
1.3
1.2
1.0
1.0
0.8
0.4
0.3
0.3
0.0
-1.0
-1.7
-2.6
-2.9
-3.2
-7.0
-8.7

Exports

0.0
11.8
9.0
0.0
5.5
3.2
0.0
6.0
7.2
9.6
1.8
0.1
11.5
1.2
0.0
5.8
2.1
-0.1
4.4
-2.3
-0.9
5.7
5.7
1.0
4.4
1.5
2.8
3.4
-4.6
-13.0
6.8
12.1
3.6
2.1
5.8
2.0
7.9
-3.2
1.3
-5.7
3.1
-14.1
-10.2
-16.0

  1. Or most recent year available. Countries sorted by GDP.

Note: Data not available for Djibouti, Eritrea, and Somalia

Source: World Bank, 1997b, Africa Regional Brief, Washington DC: The World Bank.

Appendix 3: FDI as a % of GDP and GDI in Southeast Asia and Africa, 1970-1995.

Source: Calculated from World Development Indicators, 1997.

Source: Calculated from World Development Indicators, 1997.


Return to the previous page

Return to the UNU Homepage